There are two ways of
defining economic success: relative to the rest of the world, and in itself.
Relatively, I will compare Europe with India, China and the Muslim Near East
and North Africa. In itself, I will mark the organization of Europe in the
1750’s as a success and I will describe everything that led to it as a reason
for the European economic success. The
two perspectives are mutually related: the period around the 1750’s is
considered a success because of the superiority of the European economy at that
time relative to the other countries[1].
At the beginning of the
second half of the Middle Ages Europe was not a leading power. China, India,
East Asia and the Muslims of the Middle East and North Africa were at least as
developed as Europe was at the time. Between 960 A.D. and 1127 A.D. China
underwent a period of economic success, founded upon rapid extension of rice
cultivation and a large-scale increase of both local and long-distance trade.
Such growth, often compared to that of 15th century Europe, had
never happened before in Chinese, some dare say, world history. “China became
the leading society in the world in terms of productivity per capita” [Curtin,
1986][2].
Around 1000 A.D. several
other Asian empires emerged: the Chola empire of South India, the Khmer empire
of Cambodia, and the Champa empire in Vietnam. This emergence was concurrent
with a change in the structure of trade: while earlier merchants had shipped
their goods directly from the place of production to the place of consumption,
after 1000 A.D. commercial centers, so called emporia, appeared, which
led to the exercise of re-export, and an increase in the volume of trade. In
this context the Chola empire of South India experienced an
expansion in the early eleventh century A.D. [Rothermund, 1988].
The Muslim merchants
with center Baghdad also were proliferating, as Thousand and One Nights,
a famous compilation of children’s fairytales suggests through the depiction of
the Muslim wealth and thriftiness [Lopez and Raymond, 1961]. Historians talk
about a “Muslim monopoly” over the Indian Ocean trade [Curtin, 1986].
Thus, in the beginning of
the Middle Ages Europe was not the only player. It was not even among the
flourishing ones. By the year 1750, however, she became the most prosperous,
prestigious, and prodigious continent where one could choose to live, it was
the continent where the Industrial Revolution was about to happen. Was it
circumstances or her inherent superiority that predestined her taking up the
lead?[3]
Factors that influenced the
pace of history in the advantage of Europe are favorable geography, climate in
particular, propensity towards innovation, religious dynamics, internal and
external migrations which contributed to the spread of knowledge and ideas, the
discovery and colonization of the New World, the dissolution of feudalism and
manorialism, the consequent rise of nationalism and mercantilism, and the
expansion of trade, manufacturing and agriculture.
Landes’ argument of cold climate
being superior to hot one[4]
is invalid for both empirical and theoretical reasons. Empirically, there were
times when dominant nations occupied hot regions: e.g. India, the Muslim
empire; the first cradles of civilizations appeared in hot areas: Egypt,
Shumerus and Akad, the Roman Empire. On the other hand China has a temperate
climate (and other advantages) but was not dominant in the 1750s.
Theoretically: humans are flexible and adaptive beings. They either get used to
a situation, or they correct it. Indians were never inefficient because of
heat. Of what Landes accuses them in his chapter “Why not India [accommodate
the Industrial Revolution]?” is that they were not receptive to inventions, but
he did not state idleness as a reason for it. In human history there are
numerous examples of adjustment of habits and corrections of natural phenomena
that human beings undertook: In France and Spain everything closes up between
1:00 and 4:00 so people avoid working at the hottest part of the day, but still
work an 8-hour day: 8:00-1:00 and 4:00-7:00; the Low Countries had land under
the sea level but they managed to protect it from disappearing and made gardens
out of it. Climate can only be a short-term factor that slows temporarily the
development of a nation, but it cannot be a long-term obstacle to the growth of
a country. “It would be a mistake to see geography as destiny” [Landes, 1999].
However, favorable climate with its beneficial effect on soil fertility, did
give a head start to the European development.
Propensity towards
inventions
is a characteristic of a nation that is changeable. Whether a nation is
receptive towards innovation depends on its tradition, habit and culture, that
is to say it is acquired and not inborn[5].
What happened to Europe after the fall of the Roman Empire? Europe entered a
period of regression. The organized structure that she had developed during the
history of the Roman Empire, fell apart, and in the beginning of the Middle
Ages she had to start to organize herself from scratch. She began with the
feudal system – a fall back into a lack of organization. Who would have told at
that period of time that the star of Europe would shine again 1000 years later?
In the beginning of the Middle Ages Europe had little to lose and a lot to gain
from any act of initiative or aggressiveness that she performed. While the
Indians and Muslims were controlled by their cannons, the Northmen were in
their blossom, and they robbed, raided and invaded within all of Europe. But
“the Northmen far surpassed other peoples in their daring and in their
technique of navigation on the seas… It is to the Northmen that we owe the rise
of commercial activities in northwestern Europe in the ninth and tenth
centuries.” [Barnes, 1937] While the Indians and the Chinese were happy with
the slow but sure growth of their economies [the Indians, for example,
succeeded in their trade in the Indian Ocean, but it was the Europeans, who
initiated the long-distance trade], the Europeans had the ambition of at least
reviving their previous prosperity “The dream of Rome reborn never died”
[Landes, p.34]. Ambition for growth and dominance is a good in itself. Getting
into the habit of having such ambition is the greatest luck Europe had. A more
recent example of the vice of having wealth with no ambition is 17th
century Spain. She was rich and because of that she had no incentive to develop
her industries. “Spain… became (or stayed) poor because she had too much money.
The nations that did the work learned and kept good habits, while seeking new
ways to do the job faster and better.” [Landes, p.173] “There was too much
parasitism, too many people whose ambition was to be parasites” [in reference
to 17th century Spain, Davis, 1973 p.155] It was not Spain’s
incapability or the lack of qualities of her nation, but the lack of stimulus
that compelled her to misery after centuries-long luxurious life. In the same
way it was not India’s or China’s inferiority that inhibited them from
dominating the world economy. In the 11th century both India and
China were in a period of success. Thus, the ambition of their rulers was to
maintain their status rather than to improve[6].
Maintaining requires less risk taking, discourages from financing of innovative
experiments, and makes novelties and unprecedented innovations dubious and
unnecessary. “Society is a prisoner of practices passed on from generation to
generation and altered only with difficulty.” [Duby, 1979] The propensity towards
inventions was a reason for the European Economic success, but it was dictated
by circumstances, not by an inherent quality. It was a temporary feature of
Europe[7],
not a long-lasting determinant of the European populace[8].
Religion in itself was by no means a
reason for the European economic success. “…Few realize that perhaps the
richest and most highly developed of all civilizations during the medieval
period was one that grew up under the auspices of an alien religion, namely,
Mohammedanism, or as it is more correctly called, Islam.” [Barnes, 1937 p. 111]
“It is, in fact, hardly accurate to identify Christendom with the West and
Islam with the East, at a time when Asia Minor was still a Christian land and
Spain and Portugal and Sicily were the home of flourishing Moslem culture.”
[Dawson, The Making of Europe, 1932] The fact that Christianity was
successful in 1735 does not certify its rightness or superiority: paganism was
dominant but vanished; Islam was dominant but diminished in power.
What fostered economic
success in Europe was the dynamics within Christianity. Christianity was
not a unitary religion. In the beginning of 16th century
Protestantism emerged, with its most influential branch: Calvinism.
Protestantism did give a push towards a desire for profits as opposed to wealth
because of its notion of predeterminism, which implied that whether one is
chosen by the Lord or not, is to be seen by one’s prosperity in the earthly
life. An observation was made that most scientists in a French university were
protestant despite the fact that France is Catholic, because Protestantism was
more approving of science. Catholicism was actually against a lot of
innovations and scientific discoveries, since they threatened its authority in
attaching explanations to world phenomena. Worth mentioning are the mechanic
clocks and the rotation of the Earth – the first deprived the Church of its
influence on its subjects’ daily routine, and the second, they thought,
contradicted the idea of egocentrism and Holiness of the Earth created by the
Almighty.
An economically positive
side of Christianity was its missionary impulse. Christians traveled all around
the world to preach and spread the Gospel thus initiating cultural and
intellectual exchange from both sides. The Crusades (1095-1291) are the most
significant example for that: as a consequence of them the western world became
better acquainted with the Muslim habits and achievements, and made use of the
ones they considered worthy of appropriation. The Crusades also contributed to
the development of trading relations between the East and the West.
Another positive phenomenon
is that at a certain point the religious and the secular authorities in Europe
split, so that the main decision making unit was not governed by religious laws
and was not concerned primarily with the benefit of the church. In the Muslim
world this was not the case and there the religious and the secular were
unified in one ruling body, giving a bias of all decisions towards the mosque.
Religious conflicts were a
usual occurrence and as much as they might have been unwelcome by individuals
and rulers, they were economically of benefit. They caused migrations of people
within Europe, for example from Spain (Catholic) to Netherlands (Protestant), which
contributed to diffusion of knowledge and spread of religious and non-religious
trends. India and China did not have those internal dynamics of the populace,
so necessary for the spread of ideas.
Feudalism saw its
dissolution in the period 1350 –1450. Feudalism was a stage in the evolution of
the political and economic situation in Europe characterized by protection of
the helpless members of society, and their exploitation by the noble class for
economic and military purposes. In the middle of 14th century nationalism
emerged as an alternative way of organization. Parallel to this process
occurred the substitution of manorialism with mercantilism. The manorial
system could no longer fulfill the needs of the people and in particular could
not sustain the trend towards urbanization. The creation of towns required both
agricultural and industrial surpluses: the former to allow the concentration of
people in towns, the latter to permit capital accumulation and reinvestment in
industry. With the self-sufficiency of the manor large-scale surpluses were
hardly possible. Mercantilism, on the other hand, encouraged specialization,
which in turn led to surpluses. The main change, however, was in the goal of
the national ethic. For first time the increase of wealth became the main aim
of the rulers as well as of the individuals. There were four ways of pursuing
this goal on the national scale: restrict imports through tariffs and quotas,
encourage domestic output, encourage exports through subsidies, and encourage direct
flow of gold from the colonies. Other
positive effects of mercantilism were that it encouraged the building of
infrastructure such as roads, schools, and harbors; it developed currency as a
standard unit of transaction, eliminating the confusion over multiple types of
coins with different values; it encouraged the development of financial
institutions and new business techniques; it led to the increase of the power
and importance of the merchant class.
With the development of
nationalism and mercantilism by the 16th century Europe acquired
strong and centralized national governments and experienced a commercial
expansion. The organization of the European countries gained the first features
of capitalism, like a caterpillar in its early stage of being a butterfly.
In 1492 Columbus discovered
America, named after Amerigo Vespucci – the first to explore the inland of the
new world. The discovery of the new world added another dimension to the
prosperity of Europe. Natural resources, land, and new types of vegetation and
animals[9]
enriched the European countries. Large inflows of gold entered Spain and
England, and through them – the rest of the countries. Significant number of
people moved from Europe to the new land and alleviated Europe’s hardships
caused by her population increase. As the colonies expanded they constituted
both a place where production was growing thus benefiting the crown, as well as
a territory with a huge demand for the European exports. Trade proliferated and
blossomed.
On the background of an
evolving mercantilist system, and the expansion of the European markets,
improvements in navigation and shipbuilding led to the Commercial revolution.
It was characterized with a great increase in the volume of trade. A
controversial reason for the growth of the Atlantic trading system was slavery.
According to Williams slave labor was crucial to both the increase of trade and
to the development of the Industrial Revolution (He suggests that otherwise the
Industrial Revolution might have happened later).
The growth in trade led to
an unprecedented growth of the manufacturing industry. It also
contributed to the Agricultural Revolution characterized with the
introduction of more efficient farming organization and techniques. The growth
of trade in general augmented the volume of financial transactions and this
stimulated the development of the banking system. The first central banks were
established: Bank of Amsterdam (1609) and Bank of England (1694).
On these premises modern
capitalism was initiated. Its first features to evolve were the following:
desire for profit, estimation of success and social status in terms of monetary
units, the evaluation of goods and services in terms of prices set by
bargaining, the accumulation of large monetary resources for investment in
business ventures, the existence of a free market for the trade of goods, the
presence of a sufficient labor market, a credit system adequate to the needs of
the businesses, and a development of the industrial and commercial life [Barnes,
1937].
Relative to the rest of the
world Europe succeeded because of her encouragement of invention, propensity
for innovation, and religious dynamics within her that helped the spread of
innovations, knowledge, and ideas in general. In itself Europe achieved her
level of growth in the 1750’s and established the foundations of capitalism
because of a chain of developments: the fall of feudalism and manorialism, the
consequent rise of nationalism and mercantilism, the discovery and colonization
of the new world, the expansions in trade, manufacturing and agriculture.
Favorable geography and climate gave her a head start. However, in my opinion
her success was contingent, it could have been India or China taking up the
lead. The latter did not happen because of circumstances, not because of
inherent superiority of the European organization, culture and religion. Europe
and the rest of the world were runners with similar capabilities placed at
different positions due to circumstances, and in 1750 it was still possible
that circumstances would change around. Only our knowledge of what was to
happen next allows characterizing the status of Europe in the 1750’s as an
absolute success: Europe was about to accomplish the Industrial Revolution, and
was about to fully employ the ethic of capitalism whose foundations by that
time were already established.
BIBLIOGRAPHY:
Landes, David.
(1999). Wealth and Poverty of Nations.
New York: W.W. Norton & Company.
Rider, Christine.
(1997). Introduction to Economic History. Cincinnati: International
Thomson Publishing Company
Barnes, Harry.
(1937). An Economic History of the Western World. New York: Harcourt,
Brace and Company.
Rothermund, Dietmar.
(1988). An Economic History of India. London: Croom Helm.
Curtin, Phillip.
(1986). Cross-cultural Trade in History. London: Cambridge University
Press.
Lopez, R. and Raymond, I. (1961). Medieval
Trade in the Mediterranean World.
New York: Columbia University Press.
Davis, Ralph. (1973). The
Rise of the Atlantic Economies. New York: Cornell University Press.
[1] While the success of shooting a bottle from 200 feet is an absolute term, economic success is relative. Had Europe reached the same level of development as she did, but India a higher level, then its economy at the time would not have been considered a success.
[2] Curtin, chapter 6, p. 109
[3] To clarify my concern here is an illustration: if runner A is faster than runner B, and runner A starts running one hour later than runner B, in the short-run runner B will lead, but in the long-run runner A inevitably will pull ahead; on the other hand, if runners A and B are similar in their ability to run, and A is held back for an hour, in the long-run runner B is still going to be ahead; So, was Europe held back for several centuries (the first half of the Middle Ages) and she recovered to her inherent lead, or was she put ahead by circumstances in the race between equal competitors for world dominance?
[4] Landes, 1999, chapter 1
[5] For example a person coming from a lower level has a greater drive for success and improvement than a person who is already high enough and who could afford to aim at simply maintaining his position. The Europeans during the Middle Ages were in a downfall and had the motivation to revive their earlier dominion. The Chinese and Indians did not have this urge.
[6] The striving for economic growth and increase of wealth of the nations develops first in Europe with the rise of mercantilism. The ethic of practicing scientific research and analysis and the habit of introducing innovations on a regular basis comes into being much later in time.
[7] The fact that Europe can still be considered prone to innovations does not imply causal relationship with European propensity to innovation in the Middle Ages.
[8] One might ask how can a nation change such an important trait of its character, but the Northmen mentioned above did it, why not the Europeans? “The Norse were the ancestors of the present Scandinavians: the Norwegians, Swedes, and Danes. Today, these peoples are among the most civilized, pacific, and urbane inhabitants of the earth. It is hard to imagine their progenitors a thousand years ago as brutal and bloodthirsty pirates who robbed and pillaged and murdered wholesale, without conscience or restraint.” [Barnes, 1937 p.100]
[9] E.g. potatoes and turkeys were first cultivated for food in America