In England, the need for high revenue prompted conversely higher taxes and revenue to secure them concomitant with restrictions on innovation in manufacture. Reciting a litany of various restrictions on trade and enterprise, it is suggested that American government policy had become one of diminishing, toward abolition of such restrictions on trade in reciprocal fashion: "This effect is always produced to a certain extent, by the collection of duties on imports, as the home producer is not subject to the same duties, and may, of course, sell his commodities so much higher than he could do were there no such restraint upon exchanges with foreigners." (114) The impact of such taxes is said to be always less where the imposition is "for the purpose of protecting the home producer." While it constitutes an actually heavier tax, it is not to support the government, but: " ... is paid to the home producer, and constitutes a bounty, from the payment of which the consumer derives no benefit whatsoever ..." (115) except in the long-term impact of rising levels of living standards. Even at its highest, it was never prohibitive, but was said to be ever "in a continual course of reduction." But even at the high water mark, the real value of consumption of foreign imports was nearly twice as high here as it was in Britain. (116) But by no means is Carey's protection limited to the tariff issue. He argues for internal improvement projects, most notably roads (117) which increase population and its density along with wealth creation, and lead to diminution of the proportional cost involved in supporting them. He thus attaches to the notion of protection the entire scope of governmental activity he terms public energy which is directed toward economic development and growth. For him, protection is the whole range of cultivating efforts. In a section pertaining to credit, he not only describes its impact on increasing production, productivity of labor, increased diversification, and rising "proportion retained by the labourer" (118) through the saving of labor, but places the need for a general system of credit squarely at the feet of government, sighting the Bank of America as an exemplar of the success of the system in both its engendering of industry and comparatively almost minuscule loss rate. (119) When Carey returns to the matter of support of government in Chapter Nine, he fashions a comparative evaluation of various instruments of taxation, setting (at that quite early date) on the decided preference of the income tax, by which in support of government, "every man contributes in the ratio of his interest." (120) Perhaps more importantly for the present consideration is his statement offered in that general context that : " ... it is obvious that it is to the labourer of the highest importance that government should be administered in that way which tends to permit the most rapid growth of capital." (121) Governmental expenditure has to be constrained for it is wasted, comparatively speaking, since: "The same capital left in the pockets of the producers, would build rail roads and canals, facilitating the acquisition of the means of subsistence and enjoyment." (122) Carey was not alone in such assertions, whether as to the role of public energy generally or more specifically in terms of the utility of protective tariffs. The same argumentation permeates, for example, Daniel Raymond's THOUGHTS ON POLITICAL ECONOMY. In part two of that tract, Raymond speaks of Protecting Duties as enacted toward "the encouragement of the industry of the nation."(123) Asserting "that the public interests are paramount to individual interests,"(124) he directs the argument in those terms specifically to counter the free trade arguments of Adam Smith. Green might find that chapter particularly informative regarding some of his expressions concerning Carey. And while it is beyond the scope of this essay to consider the point in any substantive manner, there are found identical assertions in A MANUAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY written by Erasmus Peshine Smith, and in Frederich List's NATIONAL SYSTEM OF POLITICAL ECONOMY. It does seem almost as though Carey at times becomes fixated upon the protective tariff mechanism, or nearly so, although clearly not to the exclusion of other 'protective' characteristics generally of the American System program. Admittedly, he does present quite a strong case for his position on duties, and it may be that such legislative enactment was a concrete measure which could be undertaken toward the ends he sought and therefore were deserving of such emphasis. Carey even tried to convince the South that protective tariffs were in their long-term interest, that even though such duties would effectively end slavery, that the South generally and individuals of the slavocracy would enjoy much better livelihood and higher standards of living and wealth as a result. Whether that would have in fact have occurred especially with any haste given at the time he was presenting the argument on the eve of the Civil War obviously is a question of little consequence since they were not going to move on it very expeditiously if at all. (125) Nor is there any way to find out what would have resulted even if he had prevailed. In any event, it requires a considerable leap of faith to suppose that the Union could have been saved on such terms in 1861 or that any hegemonic Southern grouping could or would have bought it even at all. Green also proposes that it was Carey's 'fantastic' belief that there was a "relationship between minority-group prejudice and the tariff," having been accentuated during periods of low tariffs only to fade when there were high duties.(126). Carey does argue in his ESSAY ON THE RATE OF WAGES, (127) that influxes in population to create greater consumption markets, thus driving up the rate of wages, at least ultimately. Carey published his volume SLAVE TRADE, DOMESTIC AND FOREIGN in 1853. In it, he goes beyond the question of involuntary servitude in the United States to argue for an end to the larger world system of slavery imposed by the imperial policy of Britain and its ilk: "To make men free there must be competition for the purchase of their services, and the more competitive the greater must be their value, and that of the men who have them to sell." (128) As in the more agricultural areas there is less such competition for purchasing labor: " ... labor has become more valuable, and that labor has become more free, precisely as the artisan has been enabled to take his place by the side of the ploughman -- precisely as labor has become more diversified -- precisely as small towns have arisen in which the producer of food and wool could readily exchange for cloth and iron ... and precisely, therefore, as men have acquired the power of associating with their fellow-man." (129) As labor increased, so, too, did return, economic and then political. Thus, it was also the path to republican institutional validity. He continues: "It is desired to abolish the trade in slaves. No such trade could exist were men everywhere free; but as they are not so, it has in many countries been deemed necessary to prohibit the sale of men from the land, as preliminary to the establishment of freedom." (130) Shortly thereafter, Carey adds: "If, then, we desired to stop the export of negroes from Africa, would not our object be effectively and permanently attained could we so raise the value of man in Africa ... ?" (131) In order to stop the trading of men as slaves, whether chattel, wage, or whatever, what had to be done was "to raise the value of labor at home." (132) It had been prevented by conscious efforts to limit access to machinery of industry, thus guaranteeing cheap labor. But Carey carries the argument even further at the very conclusion of the book. (133) Industry would raise the value of labor and similarly free women (who are debased and enslaved) because under prevailing economic situations, women were tied to degrading labor because they had to assist the family in working due to the 'brute labor' saddled on men. Whether the argument Carey makes that slavery was unproductive (134) was beyond question, it is clear that it was at least less productive than it otherwise could have been. It was on such grounds that Carey not only opposed slavery but also was less than laudatory of abolitionists. The situation of slaves or the economy as a whole could, for example, scarcely have improved through such schemes as the infamous 'forty acres and a mule' land redistribution plans (which Lincoln also opposed) near the conclusion of the Civil War. Green, incidentally, makes much of Carey's connection and influence on Lincoln himself and certain layers of the Administration, particularly in Treasury. (135) Even though he had participated actively in support on anti-slavery forces in Kansas, he had somewhat different responses to such actions as those by John Brown there and at Harper's Ferry. His viewpoint revolved around his harmony of interest conviction and held abolitionist efforts as ill-directed because they functioned to divide the nation and thereby undermine the very requisites which would make possible a real end to slavery. It would be possible to end slavery, but it could not be done by way of political intervention directly. In SLAVE TRADE, Carey wrote: "Neither is it necessary, because there exists 'a higher law' -- a great law of the Creator -- that will effectively extinguish the slave trade ..." (136) In the words of Arnold Green: "This higher law of the Creator is a combination of machinery, diversity of employments, and the protective tariff." (137) Carey repeatedly returned to this topic in his editorials for The New York Tribune. The South would only loose by seceding. The North did not rely on it but the South was dependent on the North. (138) In these articles, he went so far as to attribute the divisive character of abolition to Stowe's UNCLE TOM'S CABIN. He seems to have quite convinced that much of the problem of American division was traceable to the British landed aristocracy as it was to the British system generally. His basic methodology for handling this threat was once more American System program and protection. In a series of letters to Schuyler Colfax published under the title HOW TO DEFEAT ENGLAND WITHOUT FIGHTING HER, (139) he faces this perhaps the most directly, sighting the need for "a great national league' (by which he meant the harmony of interest) to, as he called it, 'Americanize' the nation. Arnold Green is rather critical of Carey regarding the seemingly limited and fixated positions he espoused on the subjects of protection and slavery. But it would seem that Green's comments are ill- founded and that he misses the whole point: "Nothing better exemplifies the limited range of both his human sympathy and intellectual grasp than the stand he took on abolition and slavery, which in the minds of most of his contemporaries overshadowed all other issues. A succession of Washington politicians pled with him to modify his monolithic insistence on the tariff in the very teeth of the rising wind, not on a humanitarian basis but on realistic political grounds ... he refused to regard slavery as a political fact, but insisted that the British system was creating a far worse slavery. He at one and the same time assured his Northern compatriots that the tariff would ultimately end slavery, and addressed Southern planters with the plea that only the tariff could save their institution -- that is, at times he phrased his appeal thus, while at other times he assured the Southern planters that the tariff ultimately would end slavery but that the planters' economic and political fortunes would thereby improve." (140) Allen Salisbury has documented Carey's view on this subject drawing on the writings of E. Peshine Smith: " ... A year ago, we had the Kansas murders on our side. Now, our opponents have the Harper's Ferry riots on theirs, and if we do not act with great caution, we shall fail to win the race ... It is my final belief that Messrs. Beecher, Phillips, and others, are in this question, the most efficient allies of the pro-slavery power." (141) The matter was also addressed by Carey in his open letter to William Cullen Bryant printed in his MISCELLANEOUS WORKS under the section "The Financial Crisis, Their Causes and Effects" (142): " ... In common with Franklin and Adams, Hancock and Hamilton, those men clearly saw that it was to the industrial element we were to look for that cement by which our people and our States were to be held together. Forgetting all the lessons they had taught, we have now so long been following in the direction indicated by our British Free Trade friends -- by those who now see, as was seen before the Revolution, in the colonial vassalage -- that already are they congratulating themselves upon the approaching dissolution of the Union, and the entire re-establishment of British influence over this northern portion of the continent. For proof of this, permit me to refer you to the following extracts from the Morning Post, now the recognized organ of the Palmerstonian government: 'If the Northern States should separate from the Southern on the question of slavery -- one which now so fiercely agitates the public mind in America -- that portion of the Grand Trunk Railway which traverses Maine, might at any day be closed to England, unless indeed the people of that State, with an eye to commercial profit, should offer to annex themselves to Canada. On military as well as commercial grounds it is obviously necessary that British North America should possess on the Atlantic a port open at all times of the year -- a port which, whilst the terminus of that railway communication which is destined to do so much for the development and consolidation of the wealth and prosperity of British North America, will make England equally in peace and war independent of the United States. We trust that the question of confederation will be speedily forced upon the attention of Her Majesty's ministers.' 'The present time is the most propitious for its discussion ... If slavery is to be the nemesis of Republican America -- it separation is to take place -- the confederated States of British North America, then a strong and compact nation, would virtually hold the balance of power on the continent, and lead to the restoration of that influence which, more than eighty years ago, England was supposed to have lost. This object, with the uncertain future of Republican institutions in the United States before us, is a subject worthy of the early and earnest consideration on the Parliament and people of the mother country.' Shall these anticipations be realized? That they must be so, unless our commercial policy shall be changed, is as certain as that the light of day will follow the darkness of night. Look where we may, discord, decay, and slavery march hand-in-hand with the British free trade system -- harmony and freedom, wealth and strength, on the contrary, growing in all those countries by which that system is resisted. Such having been, and being now the case, are you not, my dear sir, in your steady advocacy of the Carolinian policy among ourselves, doing all that lies in your power toward undoing the work that was done by the men of '76?" But it was in regard to another of the giant names of the mid-19th century that I was provided the first occasion for my own real awareness of Henry Carey -- in his liaison developed with Karl Marx in reading communication between Marx and Engels and their cohorts in North America. There also seems to have been considerable contact between the 'Carey School' and Marx's associates in this country. Charles Dana, himself a collaborator in Carey's Vespers networks, commissioned Marx to write for the Tribune. Marx's writings spanned the entire decade of the 1850's and his affiliation actually outlasted that of Carey who left the paper in 1857 over a dispute with Horace Greeley on the question of the tariff. While the comments of Marx clearly indicate both where their philosophies converge and the stature of Carey and his ideas, there is an element or exception registered by Marx which may in fact have stemmed from a lack of understanding by Marx (although he remained a steadfast ally of Northern efforts through the Civil War) of the American situation: "Carey, the American national economist, has published a new book, SLAVERY AT HOME AND ABROAD. Under 'slavery' are here included all forms of servitude, wage slavery, etc. he has sent me his book and has quoted me repeatedly (from the Tribe). I told you before that in this man's previously published works the harmony of the economic foundations of the bourgeois system was described and all the mischief was attributed to superfluous interference by the state. The state was his bogey ... The root of all evil is the centralizing effect of big industry. But this centralizing effect is England's fault because she turns herself into the workshop of the world and forces all other countries back into the rudest agriculture, divorced from manufacture. For the crimes of England the Ricardo-Malthus theory and especially Ricardo's ground rent are in their turn responsible. The necessary consequences alike of Ricardo's theory and of industrial centralization would be Communism. And in order to avoid all this, to oppose centralization by localization and a combination of factories and agriculture all over the country, the final recommendation of our ultra-free trader is -- protective tariffs. In order to escape the effects of bourgeois industry, for which he makes England responsible, he resorts like a true Yankee to hastening this development in America by artificial means. The only thing of positive interest in his book is the comparison between the former English Negro slavery in Jamaica and the Negro slavery in the United States. He shows that the main body of Negroes in Jamaica, etc,. always consisted of newly imported barbarians, as under English treatment the Negroes were not only unable to maintain their population, but lost two-thirds of the number annually imported; the present generation of Negroes in America, on the other hand, is a native product more or less Yankeeised, English-speaking, etc., and therefore fit for emancipation. Your article on Switzerland was of course a direct attack at the leader in the Tribune and their Carey. I have continued this hidden warfare in a first article on India in which the destruction of the native industry by England is described as revolutionary. This will be very shocking to them. For the rest, the whole rule of Britain in India was swinish, and is to this day."(143) In spite of the Marx-Carey association and dialogue of sorts, Marx did manage to elaborate on some problems he had with Carey's political economy. If there were parallels between their perspectives, Carey was after all still a capitalist or bourgeois economist. The capitalist system, despite its contributions acknowledged by Marx, was still the problem for him. Marx has criticized Carey for an alleged failure to see through "fortuitous distortions of [American capitalist] relationships" which differentiated the New World experience from that of Europe's "inherited obstacles of the feudal period." The problem for Carey was the English System, but Marx saw only differences embedded in their separate peculiarities. The productive relationships remained unchanged. (144) Marx further objects in the GRUNDRISSE to Carey's viewpoint that: "It is a law of nature, for example, that wages should increase with the productivity of labor," (145) and his theoretical framework of class conflict was obviously quite at odds with Carey's Harmony of Interest. But Marx's problem with Carey were actually merely Marx's own problems. he may have been too unfamiliar to appropriately distinguish the British situation from that of America. Marx had a somewhat different notion of the character of man, as well, as discussed earlier. His determinism is in sharp contrast to the will prevalent in Carey. For Marx, for whom such freedom could only arise in the 'new socialist man', much of humanity's problem arose in bourgeois society, while for Carey, capitalism was the real liberator. And yet, there are striking similarities. Perhaps not fully recognized by Marx himself, the labor theory of value he is credited with having uncovered can also be found quite before his time in Hamilton's REPORT ON MANUFACTURES, certainly a position that Carey qualifies as being in the tradition of. He clearly shared the concept with Hamilton. Carey and Marx also shared critical views of Adam Smith, Malthus, and Mill. It might even be suggested that Carey's principle of Association bore striking parallels with Marx's development of the 'class-for-itself.' Probably the most rudimentary area of convergence revolves around the idea of 'expanded reproduction' and its development out of what Marx would characterize a rising ratio of social surplus to constant and variable capital. The fact that we will not find Carey expressing it in terms of S'/ C + V aside, the similarity is profound and important The doctrine of Association is one of the central tenets of the entire system of Carey. In his last book THE UNITY OF LAW which was published in 1872, he succinctly delineates his idea of progress in terms of this combination concept: "Throughout nature, the power of combination is in the direct ratio of the individualization of the various parts. The more perfect it becomes, the more rapid is the circulation and the greater the force excited. So precisely is it with man. The more societary positives and negatives are brought together, and the more his power of association, the greater is the tendency toward development of his various faculties; the greater becomes his control of the forces of nature, and the more perfect his own power for self-direction; mental force thus more and more obtaining control over the accumulations of the past. The physically weak, and the physically strong, whether male or female, youthful or aged, tend more and more to meet on terms of strict equality ..." (146) However, this theory is not new at that juncture. In the PRINCIPLES OF POLITICAL ECONOMY, Volume II, he wrote: "The tendency to association is natural to man. It has its origin in the desire of maintaining and improving his condition. Each feels that he may derive benefit from his neighbor, and knows that to enable him to do thus he must grant aid in return."(147). The natural tendency heightens with industry and draws people more tightly together into protective communities. This protective function, Carey contends, marks the birth of government. The developing division of labor is the dynamic which motivates societal change. We also find this conceptualization articulated in THE HARMONY OF INTEREST. Man and society operate under identical laws as does the physical universe. It is as well a rudimentary formulation in his PRINCIPLES OF SOCIAL SCIENCE III. Near the end of this work, he has constructed a systematic statement of the identity of social and natural law: "That heat is a cause of motion and force -- motion being, in its turn, a cause of heat and force: That the more heat and motion produced, the greater is the tendency towards acceleration in the motion and the force: That the more the heat, the greater is the decomposition of masses, and individualization of the particles of which they are composed -- thus fitting them for entering into chemical combination with each other: That the greater the tendency towards individualization, the more instant are the combinations, and the greater the force obtained: That the more rapid the motion, the greater the tendency of matter to rise in the scale of form -- passing from the rude forms which characterize the inorganic world, through those of the vegetable and animal world, and ending in man: That, at every stage of progress, there is an extension of the range of law to which matter is subjected, accompanied by an increase of the power of self-direction -- subordination and freedom keeping steady pace with organization: That last in the progress of development comes man, the being to whom has been given the power to guide and direct himself and nature, too -- his subjection to all the laws above referred to, being the most complete." (148) It would seem to be clear that Carey was familiar with not only Oparin perhaps, but most especially Liebniz, for this is precisely his message in MONADOLOGY. This self-organizing negentropic universe is the essence of their vision of natural law. And, as Liebniz extends the physical laws to human society and social order, here Carey is echoing similar notions, which constitute the essential character of his principle of association, which is the ground out of which government sprouts. It is the basis of his concept of community. Referring back to his concept of the organic analogy of society and his argument from it to the public energy function of government as a reflection of that, we have both the general structure of Carey's natural law, and the basis of his entire political economy, and particularly, protective tariffs. Among the writings of a contemporary and colleague of Carey, Edgar Allan Poe, are a set of short stories concerning the exploits of one C. August Dupin, a French detective whom it almost seems Poe may have intended as a contrapuntal character to Sherlock Holmes. The inductive methodology Dupin espouses for checkers as opposed to chess as well as for solving crimes and dealing with people and for scientific endeavor is one Poe makes quite more of in his essay EUREKA. Poe was active in Whig Party circles and enjoyed publication through the house of Matthew Carey. For Henry Carey, too, the only proper social science would have to be grounded in such bases involving association and induction. While he insisted that it must become more mathematical to approach classification as true science, deductive reasoning would be inadequate. It is necessary, Carey says drawing on Goethe in PRINCIPLES OF SOCIAL SCIENCE II (149) to study the "breath of the spirit" rather than "individual material parts." As the "subject of social science," man, says Carey, is "the molecule of society." Continue 1