IT PAYS TO STAY; THE FINANCIAL PAGE Series: 5/5 |
In the late nineties, the city of Toledo, Ohio, faced a crisis. DaimlerChrysler,
which ran a Jeep factory there, announced plans to build a new plant, but
offered no guarantee that it would be built in Toledo. So the city and the
state came a-courting. They promised Daimler a ten-year exemption from all
property taxes, offered hundreds of millions of dollars in tax credits, and
bought out eighty-three homes and sixteen small businesses, in order to give
the company more land. Crisis averted: Daimler is still building Jeeps in
Toledo.
This arrangement, while extraordinarily generous, is fairly typical. Across
the country, cities and states routinely lavish on companies what economists
call "location-based incentives." No one outside of Ohio would have
paid Toledo's largesse much mind had it not been for a surprising development:
a few months ago, the Sixth Circuit Court of Appeals, in Cincinnati, found that
Daimler's tax credits in Toledo were unconstitutional. (The Court ruled that
the credits interfered with interstate commerce, which only Congress has the
power to regulate.) Months, or years, of appeals lie ahead, but, for the moment
at least, much of what we know as corporate welfare may be technically illegal.
Thirty years ago, such news wouldn't have meant much. Cities and states used
to lure new businesses the old-fashioned way: cheap labor, low crime rates,
good schools, better country clubs. Beginning in the seventies, though, the
combination of stagflation, increased global competition, and greater corporate
mobility turned local governments into rival suitors showering companies with
the Chamber of Commerce equivalents of flowers and chocolates. With tax breaks,
cheap loans, and outright giveaways, states and local communities hand out
almost fifty billion dollars in incentives every year. The logic is simple
enough: businesses create jobs, so governments should do whatever it takes to
attract them. And even though tax breaks are rarely the determining factor in
where companies choose to go--Irvine, California, for example, has become an
auto-industry hub without offering any tax breaks at all--companies would be
foolish to turn down free money. So they have mastered the location-shopping
racket, pitting cities against each other in search of a sweetheart deal.
The cities are often easy marks. The classic example, of course, is the new
sports stadium: a team threatens to leave, and the home town panics, spending
hundreds of millions of dollars on a white elephant. But it happens with other
businesses as well. New York City has been one of the worst offenders,
especially under former Mayor Rudolph Giuliani. It gave hundreds of millions of
dollars in tax breaks to firms that weren't going anywhere; most infamously,
Giuliani committed the city to subsidizing a new, billion-dollar headquarters
for the New
York Stock Exchange, amid implausible threats that it would move to New
Jersey. (Michael Bloomberg quashed that plan upon taking office. He also renounced
incentives that he'd been granted to keep his own company's headquarters in New
York.) What's more, corporate welfare is fertile ground for cronyism and
political favoritism.
Obviously, cities have reason to dangle a lure. A recent study by Enrico
Moretti, of U.C. Berkeley, and Michael Greenstone, of M.I.T.,
which compared cities that had competed against each other for new plants,
found that the winners generally had benefitted--they had slightly higher tax
revenues and increased property values. The problem is that though the city
with the new plant may be better off, collectively we are all worse off, because
the tax money spent on corporate welfare could otherwise go to more productive
uses, such as education and infrastructure. For the American economy, it
doesn't matter whether Daimler builds Jeeps in Toledo or Kalamazoo; whatever
one city spends to outdo the other is money thrown away.
All public spending distributes benefits unevenly, but the sheer
capriciousness of the incentive process makes the inequity worse. Among the
plaintiffs in the Toledo case were three of the city's small businesses, which were
understandably annoyed at seeing their tax proceeds padding Daimler's profits.
The corporate-welfare system encourages state and local governments to create
an uneven playing field and puts them in the position of deciding which
businesses deserve a leg up--in effect, making big bets with public money. When
these bets backfire, it can hurt. Last year, Indianapolis lost more than a
thousand jobs when United
Airlines shut down a maintenance center for which the city, the county, and
the state had pitched in hundreds of millions of dollars. And the small town of
Galesburg, Illinois, spent a decade plying Maytag
with incentives only to watch the company shut down a refrigerator plant and
move production to Mexico. The local district attorney has threatened to sue Maytag,
but has been opposed by Galesburgers who fear scaring off other businesses.
People in local government know that they should kick the habit. In the
early nineties, at a meeting in Washington, D.C., the nation's governors
pledged to invest in "improvements to the general economic climate"
rather than in "subsidies for individual projects and companies." But
that pledge didn't last. States and cities are trapped in a prisoner's dilemma:
as long as one town can woo a corporation with baubles and tax breaks, every
town has to be willing to do so. That Toledo decision may be their only hope.
The business of America shouldn't be subsidizing business.