I am most pleased to have this further opportunity of addressing the Bretton
Woods Committee,
and I would like to thank you for this further evidence of your interest
in and support for the IMF,
so effectively demonstrated recently in very demanding circumstances for
the Fund.
It is a little over a year since I last spoke to you. Since then the world
has passed through a period
of deep turbulence. This led to determined and at times controversial action
by governments and
institutions around the world. Possibly before I elaborate on my topic
today, you would like to
hear briefly from the horse's mouth, what is the outlook now. Certainly,
the worst of the emerging
market crisis seems to be behind us. In Asia, the countries at the heart
of the crisis are close to or
even past the turning point: Korea in particular is seeing an upturn in
activity, obliging us to revise
upward our forecast to 4 percent perhaps more.
But we also have good news from Thailand, as well as the Philippines which
shielded itself pretty
well against the worst of the crisis by implementing courageously their
kind of precautionary
program with the IMF. And the news is also good from Indonesia where the
positive effects of the
program were delayed by political imbalances but where we are happy to
see now, not only the
first truly free, peaceful, and orderly elections in more than 40 years,
but also that, this year growth
is expected to become positive, with inflation falling to the single digit
level. This, together with
stability of the exchange rate, would allow the reduction of interest rates,
further improving
prospects for recovery, while market confidence.
Let us have no illusion. All of this is still extremely fragile and requires
increased vigilance so that
complacency does not reappear. But let me state that there are now good
prospects for these
countries to resume growth-high-quality growth-on a more sustainable basis
than before the crisis.
A heavily damaged financial system, a gravely weakened corporate sector,
many structural
rigidities, not to mention corruption, cronyism, and nepotism, were key
among the underlying
causes of the crisis. By dealing with these issues up front, governments
restored confidence in
economic policy and laid the basis for a resumption of high-quality growth.
We helped them in
doing that, we do not apologize for that, and we are grateful to our membership
who supported us
in these difficult and, at times innovative, but indispensable steps. I
would say the same about the
measures of social progress, particularly for the core labor rights our
dialogue with the authorities
has helped to provide.
* * * * *
There is no need to speak about Brazil and other countries. More generally,
the question is
whether this tentative recovery can be extended into a new era of high-quality
global growth, in
which the emerging markets will play a dynamic role once again? That will
depend, not just on
skillful macroeconomic management, but also on whether the international
community can advance
convincingly with the challenge, on which it has embarked, to overhaul
the architecture of the
international financial and monetary system.
And in this debate, no topic has proved more challenging than the question
of how to "involve the
private sector in forestalling and resolving crises". You have invited
me today to address this
question, in this session entitled "Bailing in the private sector in debt
crises." In my remarks today I
shall not try to review the whole range of reform issues that are being
debated by the international
community, but instead will reflect on what should be expected of the private
sector creditor and
debtors, touching where necessary on the implications for their relationships
with their
governments. But two remarks in starting. First, "bailing in" carries connotations
of "bailing out",
and I do not accept that this is either the purpose or the effect of IMF
or other international
packages of financial support. Some in this audience may be able to attest
at first hand to the
losses that many investors have suffered as a result of the crises in the
emerging markets. Second,
rather than focus only on crises, my message is that "an ounce of prevention
is better than a pound
of cure", and that the bulk of our attention should be focused on strengthened
national and
international systems, even when there is no hint of crisis. Of course,
crises cannot be avoided
altogether, and therefore part of our work is to develop measures that
will facilitate the resolution
of crises if they occur.
If there is any characteristic distinguishing this series of crises from
others, it is the prominence of
the private sector-financial institutions and corporations-on both sides
of the equation as creditors
and debtors. It is instructive to contrast the recent round of crises with
earlier ones, especially the
debt crisis of the 1980s. With the explosive growth and increasing integration
of the capital
markets during the past decade, a number of notable trends stand out, all
of which have tended to
increase complexity:
· The domestic private sector-both banking and corporate-is typically
a much more
significant player now. Domestic financial and capital markets have sprung
up around the
world. Who would have forecast a decade and a half ago equity markets in
Beijing,
Warsaw, Prague, or Moscow?
· The "foreign investment community" is far more diverse: direct
investors, portfolio
investors, banks, bondholders, and other creditors have all become major
players.
· The different types of investment have responded to crisis in
very different ways. Even in
this most difficult of periods, flows of direct investment have not flagged:
they rose strongly
in 1997 and held fairly steady in 1998. By contrast, banks having been
the largest source of
net inflows in 1996, had become major recipients of net outflows by 1998,
the first full year
of crisis.
· It is too simple to conceive of nations as belonging to one camp
or the other: debtor or
creditor. There are powerful flows in many directions. For instance, the
largest source of
direct foreign investment in Asia is Asia. Korea, Hong Kong, Thailand,
Taiwan Province of
China and, of course, Japan, are all important sources of foreign investment
within the
region, and remain so despite having been at the heart of the crisis.
These very selective observations point to some simple truths about markets.
For much of the
1990s the markets were doing what they do best: seeking opportunities.
The crises that appeared
first in Mexico in 1994/95 and re-emerged with greater virulence during
the past two years
revealed that market players, regulators and policymakers had not fully
perceived the risks,
including some that were of systemic proportions, that accompanied those
opportunities. And so,
the second half of the 1990s, especially the past two years, have been
devoted to seeking
measures that aim to reform the critical features of the international
financial system that were
associated with the crises.
Inevitably, early attention has focussed on the resolution of crisis. The
severity of the situation
demanded an immediate response, but this was a new breed of crisis for
which precedents were
quite limited or only relatively relevant. Therefore we have in effect
been developing a still
incomplete body of "case law" based on the different experiences we had
to go through. If there is
one clear lesson to emerge from the experience it is that the diversity
of country situations means
that there is no "silver bullet", no "one-size-fits-all" solution. The
circumstances and workouts of
debt in each of the major crisis countries during the past two years have
differed substantially-from
the "concerted rollover" of a large volume of short-term debt in Korea,
to the "consultative
approach" adopted by Brazil, even though there was no intention and no
need to consider debt
restructuring. In Thailand and Indonesia different approaches were taken
again. In all of these
cases the cooperative approach stands in sharp contrast with Russia's disorderly
and highly
disruptive suspension of debt service.
* * * * *
What kind of conclusions can we draw at this stage? Let me start with the
obvious, if we are to
build a more durable, integrated international financial system, the foundation
for successful crisis
resolution should exist long before crisis strikes. Quite simply, it should
consist of the basic and
effective market structures, practices and relationships that should exist
under normal conditions.
We need to foster a mature market, which is based on stable relationships
among players that rely
on enlightened self-interest, and in which official involvement can be
limited to establishing strong
legal, regulatory and supervisory frameworks.
What should we expect from the players, regulators, and supervisors in
this market? As I review
some of these expectations, I think you will quickly recognize that what
I am calling for are the
simple, basic values of good governance, transparency and cooperation.
I. Let us first think of the responsibilities of debtors. At the top of
the list, clear and unambiguous,
is the principle that contracts must be honored. I emphasize this at every
opportunity, since it is the
very foundation of the successful operation of mature markets. Proposals
for involving the private
sector, far from encouraging countries to take their commitments less seriously,
must ensure that
obligations are honored.
If there is an equivalent singular responsibility of governments, then
it is the obligation to pursue the
macroeconomic policy objectives of stability and growth within a transparent
economic and
financial policy framework, including the dissemination of comprehensive,
accurate, and timely
data.
Other obligations involve elements of a shared responsibility, and call
for extensive cooperation
and consultation:
· A strong legislative framework-including a workable bankruptcy
law-and an independent
judicial system;
· Adoption and adherence to internationally accepted standards of
disclosure and
governance. Even if some of these standards are still "work-in-progress",
there are many
that can be adopted already;
· The development of a robust regulatory and supervisory framework
for the financial
sector;
· Policies and practices that promote sound debt management and
the high-frequency
monitoring of private external liabilities, a key aim of which should be
to avoid excessive
short-term debt.
II. How can creditors, in other words the private sector-and their governments-contribute
to a
better system?
The first area is risk assessment and risk management. You do not need
me to tell you that
investment of any kind involves risk, carrying with it the obligation to
develop adequate techniques
and practices for assessing, pricing and managing risk. Many investors
have taken substantial
losses in the past two years, and are increasingly interested in and capable
of differentiating among
countries. But investors would do well continually to keep their practices
under review, and
national regulators should ensure that this happens.
Second, creditors can play an important role in encouraging adherence to
internationally
recognized standards. Not only should they themselves expect to adopt them-for
instance by
attaining high standards of disclosure-but they can also encourage borrowers
to adopt good
practices by factoring this into their investment and pricing decisions.
Third, creditors should accept that national authorities need to adapt
the principles and standards
that support their regulation and supervision of national financial systems.
One practical suggestion,
which has gained widespread support, is to reflect more adequately the
risk of lending to emerging
markets by increasing the risk weights assigned to short-term lending in
the balance sheet of
creditor banks under the Basle Core Principles. On this, we welcome the
consultation document
released by the Basle Committee last week. More generally, I am happy that
the activities of
offshore funds, and highly leveraged institutions-including hedge funds
and the similar operations of
other financial institutions-and the role of short-term credit, will be
the subject of the first studies
by the recently established Financial Stability Forum.
Fourth, private creditors can help-and in a few cases already are helping-countries
to preserve
their foreign exchange liquidity when there is a threat of contagion by
establishing contingent
financing arrangements that can be activated if crisis looms.
Fifth, since cooperation is vital, debtors and creditors need to establish
and activate good lines of
communication during normal times. Some recent cases of debt workouts-for
instance
Indonesia-have pointed to the importance of timely and effective consultation
among debtors and
creditors. Here countries may consider emulating Mexico's practice, established
after the 1994/95
crisis, of regular consultation with international financial market participants,
and Brazil's
consultative approach to its creditors in the context of securing a voluntary
rollover of interbank
and trade related credit lines.
III. How can the IMF contribute? Less than two months ago the Fund took
an innovative
decision, which will enable it to offer financial resources to support
crisis prevention, through the
mechanism known as Contingent Credit Lines. These lines are designed to
help countries that are
in a relatively strong situation-with sound macroeconomic management, strong
financial systems,
and making progress in applying internationally recognized standards-withstand
the pressure on
their balance of payments that might arise from a sudden loss of confidence
through contagion
from developments elsewhere.
This will not divert us from our traditional activities. As a matter of
fact, a defense in preserving the
stability of the international financial system will always be our bilateral
and multilateral surveillance,
it is important for us to strengthen this function. And indeed, we are
broadening the coverage of
our surveillance:
· our consultations with members now routinely encompass financial
sector issues, in
collaboration with the World Bank and other agencies; and
· responding to the mandate given by the Interim Committee, we have
begun to develop
approaches that will promote the dissemination and application of standards
and codes of
good practice, among the entire membership.
All of this notwithstanding, we continue to update the technical assistance
and training we offer to
help countries build up their institutional capacity to manage their economies
and to handle changes
in their financial systems. And we continue to offer financial assistance
to countries that have
encountered balance of payments difficulties and are taking active steps
to overcome the
underlying causes of the imbalances. Business as usual, if I may say so.
* * * * *
In spite of that, of course, occasionally crises will occur and, we need
to be ready with measures
to assist in their resolution. This requirement entails a delicate balance
among the objectives of
preserving countries' market access in normal times, ensuring equitable
treatment of creditors if
crisis strikes, and avoiding debtor and creditor moral hazard. All of that
of course through
market-based and market-friendly solutions. In particular, making sure,
to start with, that
measures intended to resolve crisis avoid the perverse effect of precipitating
them.
The complexity of the issues arises because workable arrangements must
consist not only of ex
ante measures that are ready in case the threat from contagion develops.
They should also offer
mechanisms-or at least some principles-for resolving "extreme situations",
where crisis has
deepened to such an extent that normal payments can no longer be sustained.
Among ex ante measures and without further mentioning due attention to
management of risk, I
refer again to contingent financing arrangements from private lenders that
could be an early
recourse if crisis develops. This is one of the few ideas that can actually
be said to be in place and
workable, even if it is on a modest scale; three countries-Argentina, Indonesia,
and Mexico-have
concluded such arrangements. This deserves to be encouraged. But what when,
as in a number of
recent cases, it does not appear feasible to address the crisis by mobilizing
new resources? Many
questions arise then, including whether sovereign bonds should be included
in comprehensive debt
restructuring. We probably still have a lot to learn from the present case-by-case
approach. But
broadly speaking, bondholders must be viewed as a category of investors
at par with others,
needing to assess and price risk, and who, just like other creditors, cannot
expect public funds
from the international community to shield them from adverse outcomes.
This being said, no
debtor would wish to take default lightly, since, no matter how careful
an approach is taken,
debtors will perceive that their credibility has been most severely undermined
and investors'
confidence shaken. However, investors and debtors may have to accept that
in extremis, a
country may have no orderly way out of the crisis other than a comprehensive
debt restructuring
that includes bonds.
These issues again highlight the critical importance of debtors and creditors
maintaining a dialogue
that is established in good times, and is sufficiently robust to continue
through periods of stress.
Given the very large number of creditors that now typify many emerging
market situations, one
promising avenue is to introduce collective action clauses into new bond
contracts. Rescheduling
could then take place with the consent of a predetermined large majority
of creditors rather than
requiring unanimous consent as currently is the case in many contacts.
This is an approach that
may well require industrial country borrowers to lead the way, an issue
that is currently under
consideration.
And lastly, we must recognize that there may be a few instances in which,
despite good faith
efforts by countries to reach agreement with their creditors, agreement
cannot be secured and
default cannot be avoided. In such cases it will be important to keep proper
working relations:
debtors should seek to reestablish good faith negotiations with their creditors
promptly, and both
sides should be able to do so without finding that the process is blocked
by a handful of dissident
creditors. This has raised the questions whether and how the international
community might
introduce a temporary stay on legal action by creditors during the negotiations
between a country
and its creditors. One option-in the interest of both creditors and debtors-is
to reach agreement on
an interpretation or an amendment of the Fund's Articles of Agreement to
allow it to declare such
a stay. This suggestion has given rise to lively debate and consensus is
not yet in sight, but I see it
as an avenue worth pursuing, as-I repeat-both creditors and debtors have
a distinct interest in an
orderly process.
* * * * *
I conclude this review of the framework for a mature relationship between
creditors and debtors,
by suggesting that we need to be prepared for exactly those extreme cases
that such a mature
relationship should make highly infrequent. This is precisely our objective
in joining forces for crisis
prevention. As a matter of fact, you may observe that I have covered a
number of rather technical
topics. I have not unveiled any kind of grand design, and my suggestions
in this central field of the
role of the private sector in strengthening the international financial
architecture could be seen as
quite down to earth. But let me view them for one last minute in the broader
context we are
striving to establish, which is an environment where:
· Governments should be convinced to pursue sounder macroeconomic,
financial and
structural policies;
· Central banks should be convinced to establish more appropriate
exchange market
arrangements;
· Prudential authorities should adapt their supervisory methods,
rules and cooperation to the
ever-evolving financial activities;
· All actors would be encouraged to accept the golden rule of transparency
and the new
sets of standards and codes of good practice currently being elaborated
by various
international bodies;
· All countries would move forward in an orderly but ambitious progress
toward capital
account liberalization.
Then one can see that, yes, a new architecture is patiently being established,
a new framework is
taking shape where your institutions and countries could deepen their cooperation
in their mutual
interest, in pursuit of a more stable, safer, and more prosperous world.