Chapter
3
Eminent
scholars express different views on the meaning of rural development.
Rural
development has defined as a process of endless variety having as its main
objective the overall balanced and proportionate well-being of rural people. How
it works, and the shape it takes, it determined and influenced but many factors
in the rural area of the country (Poostchi, 1986).
Another
definition, considers rural development as a process which leads to a rise in
the capacity of rural people to control their environment resulting from more
extensive use of the benefits which ensure from such a control (Webster, 1975).
Robert
Chamber defines Rural Development as “a strategy to enable a specific group of
people, poor rural women and men, to gain for themselves and their children more
of what they want and need. It involves helping the poorest among those who seek
a livelihood in the rural areas to demand and control more of the benefits of
development. The group indicates small-scale farmers, technical and landless”
(Chamber, 1983:147).
Rural
development, in general, is a strategy designed to improve the economic and
social institution of people in rural settlement and, in particular, it focus is
on the rural poor, comprising the small scale farmers, tenants and landless.
Since rural development intended to reduce poverty, it much clearly designed to
increase production and raise productivity. Rural development recognizes,
however, that improve food supplies and nutrition, together with the basic
services such as health education, can not only directly improve the physical
well-being and quality of life of the rural poor, but can also directly enhance
their productivity and their ability to contribute to the national economy
(World Bank, 1975a).
Further
more the World Bank summaries the strategy of rural development is “A strategy
for rural development must recognize three points. Firstly the rate of transfer
of people out of low productivity agricultural and other related activities into
more rewarding pursuits has been; and given the relative size of the modern
sector in most developing countries, it will remain slow. Secondly the mass of
people in rural areas of developing countries face varying degrees of poverty,
their position is likely to get worse if population expands at unprecedented
rates and while limitation continue to be imposed by available resources,
technology, and institutions and organizations. Thirdly, rural areas have labor,
land and least some capital which, if mobilized could reduce poverty and improve
the quality of live. This implies further development of existing resources,
including the constraints of infrastructure such as road and irrigation works,
the introduction of new types of institutions and Organizations’ (World Bank,
1975a).
The
United Nations Commission of Africa, in 1971 (as quoted by Dale and Iddagoda,
1997:23), has given the definition of rural development: “Rural Development is
the outcome of a series of quantitative and qualitative change occurring among a
given rural population and those converging effects indicate, in time, a rise in
the standard living of favorable changes in the way of life of the people
concerned. It does not mean isolated programmes of ‘ Rural Development ’,
’ rural animation’, ‘mass education’, ‘agricultural extension’ or
any of other terms applies to sectoral programmes which carried out in the rural
areas or within the rural community. It means, rather, a comprehensive
development of rural area…rural development should analyzed both from the
standpoints of increase production… and from the social advancement”.
Setty
has given the definition of rural development, in a comprehensive sense, is a
process of social action in which the people communities organize themselves for
planning and action, define their common and individual needs and problems, make
plans to solve their problems, execute these plans with maximum reliance upon
community resources, and supplement these resources, when necessary, with
services and material from government and non-governmental agencies outside the
community. The thrust in rural development is people participation in the total
process and simultaneous improvements of quality of their lives. The process of
organizing rural communities for development involves working and interacting
with the people in the communities (Setty, 1991:17).
Asian
Development Bank’s Regional Seminar on Rural Development (ADB, 1988 as quoted
by Dale and Iddagoda, 1997) clarified the overall objectives of rural
development policy as:
·
preventing further
impoverishment;
·
increase production;
·
distributing rural assets
equitably;
·
eliminating poverty through
adequate wage employment and / or transfer of more productive assets and skills
to rural poor;
·
improving the quality of rural
life by providing infrastructure and social services;
·
enabling rural people to share
control over their environment and the use of local resources and participate in
decisions affecting their lives;
·
Strengthening existing rural
institutions so that they play a progressive role in development and building
new institutions, which support self-sustained development.
For
most of the definitions of rural development are focus on the improvement the
quality of life of the rural people. In the reality, the rural development
comprises all for improving, such as the agricultural productivity, increase
employment and ultimately for higher income of the target rural people or group,
in addition to providing them with minimum acceptable levels of health, food,
shelter and education (Setty, 1988:14). The rural poor are the main target group
for the rural development in the developing countries.
The
successful of efforts for implementing rural development programme, the first
essential step is the definition of the rural poor. The absent of clarity on
this point will results in ineffective coverage of the target groups as well as
in the livelihood of richer farmers taking full advantage of benefits provided
under the rural development programmes (FAO,1974).
The
poor are highly visible in most countries of the world. They include people who
are chronically hungry, it not starving; they are most often malnourished and
frequently diseased. The poor are usually illiterate or insufficiently educated.
They are badly clothed and lice in ramshackle housing and unsanitary conditions.
Almost by definition, the poor lack sufficient resources to purchase food and
other necessities of life as well as to enjoy the living conditions that are
customary in their societies. The purchasing power of the poor is so low that
they are excluded from ordinary living pattern, and customs and activities (ESCAP,
1985). The poor other things in common, apart from their extremely low income. A
disproportionate number of them-perhaps two in five-are children under 10,
mainly in large families.
Because
of the adverse circumstances, in which they live and work, the poor rarely have
the opportunity to improve the lot in life. For example, they frequently have
insufficient access to water modern agricultural inputs and in particular,
credit. They also face many disincentives to increasing the level of production
because tendency arrangements are structured to fervor landlords or a
moneylender who normally receives the greater share of any productive increases
(World Bank, 1980).
There
are factors that burden the poor. Chief among them is the fact that they are
frequently excluded from the development process. The poor lack social status
and they normally do not have the power or opportunity to participate in
designing projects or development programmes that would help them to breakout of
the cycle of poverty.
The
World Bank, in its World Development Report for 1980, Stated that “ (although)
it is difficult to measure the extent of poverty- no one seriously doubts that a
very large number of people are extremely poor. Not is the serious disagreement
about who the poor are. Half of the people in absolute poverty line in South
Asia, mainly in India and Bangladesh…overwhelmingly dependent on agriculture
– the majority of them landless (or nearly dandless) laborers.” (Srinivasan
and Bardhan, 1988:1)
Credit
is considered as an important instrument in helping small farmers and
agricultural development. Ellis. (1992) has defined “ credit is a sum of money
in the favor of the person to whom control over it is transferred. The provision
of credit involves two parties a lender and a borrower. It also involves a price
for the transfer of control over money, which is the interest rate charge by the
lender to the borrower”.
In relation to credit, Mollett (1984) states that “ There is
considerable agreement that increased farmer credit is a vital need in
developing countries, and many have introduced credit programmes. Credit is
particularly necessary to finance increased use of new inputs and thus to
increase production and income.”
In the 1950s and early 1960s, credit provision was considered a key
instrument for breaking the ‘vicious circle’ of low income, low savings and
low productivity. In mid 1960s, and up to the present time, small farmers and
the rural poor have increasingly become the chief target of credit intervention
(Ellis, 1992).
Ellis (1992) states the objectives of credit policies, and reasons for
their popularity with governments and aid donors alike are summarized as
follows:
1.
to alleviate a critical constraint hampering growth in agricultural
output, this constraint being lack of cash to make needed farm investments
(irrigation, drainage, pumps, tractors, buildings) and to purchase modern
variable inputs (fertilizer, pesticides, fuel, feeds, etc.);
2.
to replace the fragmented and incomplete rural financial market presented
by private moneylenders, this credit sources supposedly having the effect of
impoverishing their clients rather than assisting them to improve their
productivity;
3.
to accelerate the adoption of new technology by peasant farmers by
providing working capital for the seasonal purchase of variable inputs and
thence optimizing the complementarily between inputs essential for the success
of Green Revolution technology;
4.
to assist small farmers to overcome their inability to borrow from
commercial or informal credit sources due to lack of collateral and lack of
information;
5.
to provide short-term credit in order to bridge seasonal and temporary
cash shortfalls of small farmers, compared to the medium and long term lending
preferences of commercial financial institutions;
6.
to achieve equity goals, whether these are related to inter-rural,
inter-regional, or rural urban income distribution;
7.
to offset disincentive effects for small farmers of policies unfavorable
to them including low output prices, over-valued exchange rates, and inefficient
market interventions by the state;
8.
to gain favor with farmers for political purposes, including forthcoming
election, and so on;
9.
to make advantage of sometimes overwhelming generosity of foreign aid
donors, who seem to be prepared to pump large amounts of money endlessly into
rural credit projects.
In discussing the nature of the problem in rural credit, IFAD (1985)
summaries five main issues are raised, that is:
Chronic
poverty means becoming accustomed to poverty, an can also accustomed to the
physical conditions, social relationship, economic restrictions that perpetuate
it. Aspiration may still exist but hey may be difficult to articulate. The poor
themselves may be reluctant to use credit services unless they are confident of
the results.
Local economic
conditions
Local
economic in rural areas is often controlled by small elite group of landlords,
traders and moneylenders. Their control can extend both to production and
consumption. Outside intervention in the form of credit for production may help
the rural poor temporarily bat fall short of achieving an equitable
re-structuring of production relation.
Physical conditions
Often,
the inequities that exist in rural communities are caused, or exacerbated by
their physical isolation. New roads, new markets and improved supply routes for
agricultural inputs may have to be link to services.
National policies
The
success of credit scheme also depends on the national policy frameworks in which
they are implemented. If the terms of food and cash crops between rural and
urban areas are biased against the rural poor, credit for additional production
will have only limited impact.
Technical issues
The
uses to which credit is put must be viable. New technical packages for
agriculture must be proven before they are linked to credit schemes on a wide
scale. If existing agricultural practices are to be supported by credit there
must be some confident that repayment schedule can be net.
Donald (1976:34) concluded that credit programme to be successful in
increasing output, there must be an opportunity for small farmers to utilize
additional capital profitably, which requires an improvement in technology
backed by markets that can supply the necessary inputs and absorb the output.
Hulme and Mosley (1996) as quoted by Johnson and Rogaly (1997), has
designed features for ensuring high repayment rates on loans and enabling poor
people to access credit are summarized in the table below:
Table
3.1 Design
Features for Ensuring High Repayment Rates on Loan and Enabling the Poor People
Access to Credit
Design Feature |
Intended Effect |
¶
Access Method Maximum/ income assets Small loan size Regular meetings |
(Means of ensuring that relatively well-off people do
not crowd out others’ access
to loans) Direct
exclusion of better-off through eg land-holding ceiling Loans are small enough that better-off are not
interested in them Indirect exclusion of better-off through compulsory
attendance at weekly meetings or contributions of physical labor to which
the wealthy will not agree |
· Screening
Techniques Market
Interest
rate Self-selected
Character
reference |
(Mechanisms
for screening out bad borrowers and rejects) Encourages
loan taking on basis of prospective returns not to capture subsidies Prospective members are asked to form groups
themselves and hence screen of favor of those they believe will repay,
they also screen
proposed loan use Alternatively local officials or power structure may
be used to approve loan applications |
¸ Incentives to pay Insinuative
supervision Peer
group monitoring Borrowers
incentives Agency
staff Incentive Progressive
lending Compulsory
Savings |
(Mechanisms for giving borrowers who have no
collateral incentives to repay, or failing this,
forcing them to repay) Regular
meetings with extension staff in or near the homes of borrowers Repayment is made in public in front of the group with consequent lost
of face if payment is not made Agency staff may receive financial bonuses directly
related to the repayment
performance of their clients Agency
staff may receive financial bonuses directly related to the repayment
performance of their clients Borrowers
are able to gain repeated access to loans if they repay and these may also
increase in size A
small amount contributed regularly into a group savings fund provides
insurance or collateral for the loans of all group members |
Source: Hulme and Mosley, 1996 as quoted by Johnson and
Rogaly (1997)
The
design of credit project is by no mean easy. The provision of credit alone may
not always suffice when poverty is also perpetuated by social, cultural,
technical and wider economic factors (IFAD, 1985).
IFAD
(1985) concluded that: The provision of credit can be one of the most powerful
means of reaching the poor directly and preferentially. Even modest loans – on
manageable terms- can represent a sufficient improvement in the access of the
poor to resources to enable them to achieve significant increase in living
standard.
In
the rural economy it has been found that the landlords and traders take on
additional roles as moneylenders and provide capital needed, through at very
high interest rates. The informal financial intermediaries have often been
denounced as unusers and exploiters (Ambali, 1995).
The
stated objectives of various government intervention in to the rural financial
markets is to provide low interest loan to farmers and to displace the
information intermediaries out from the system. To this end, several countries
have instituted agricultural cooperatives, rural credit banks and legal
directives to commercial banks to advance a certain percentage of lending to the
farmers. But in this, a considerable number of population in various countries,
especially in poor Asian countries where marginal farmers, landless,
wage-laborers and other off-farm laborers excluded from the conventional banking
systems (Murshid, 1991).
The
following describe briefly some initiative for rural lending in selected Asian
countries:
Thailand:
In Thailand, there is a Bank of Agriculture and Agriculture Cooperative (BAAC)
which was created in 1966 for assisting agricultural development and increasing
living standards of the rural people. In 1975, the Royal Government of Thailand
relaxed restriction on the opening of new commercial bank branches in rural
areas.
The
total amount of agricultural credit by the commercial bank and BAAC increased
dramatically form 1, 305 million Baht in 1974 to 412, 063 million Baht in 1983.
The government is big shareholders of BAAC. In 1994, BAAC, operating fund
totaled 132,505 million Baht consisted of different sources and the numbers of
BAAC’s clients reached more than 4.3 million clients, and each in average can
borrow about $500. The farmers can receive the loan directly to BAAC or through
Agricultural Cooperatives. BAAC become famous to rural Thai farmers, which is an
important source of providing rural credit. Moreover, BAAC also assist farmers
and farmers institutions in marketing, so that farmers can sell their produce at
fare price. In the economic recession, Asian economic crisis, this bank has
increased the interest rate, which depend on the rate of inflation (BAAC annual
report, 1994).
BAAC
faces some major problems in the its implementation are the followings:
(1)
Unable to pay credit, this problem is faced only by some of the farmers
who faced natural disaster, i.e. flood and drought that persist almost every
yea,
(2)
Insufficient farmers knowledge about the procedure of getting the credit,
this problem motivated the farmers to find out loan from middlemen with high
interest rate,
(3)
Not proper use of loan and
(4)
Weak capacity of collateral, (Rural-Regional Planning Workshop Peport, 1998).
Bangladesh: In
Bangladesh, Grameen Bank is a famous financial institution was established in
1976. This bank started to provide credit for the poor by organizing
agricultural and handicraft production, small businesses and house building.
Starting capital of the Grameen bank consisted: 60% was from the government, and
the other 40% from the borrowers.
Up
till now the Grameen bank has been playing a very important role in the
socio-economic life of Bangladesh. Currently, Grameen bank has savers more than
2 million and borrowers more than 1.9 million. For 17 years, until August 1993,
Grameen bank disbursed about $743 million to the poor farmers. In 1993, Grameen
bank disbursed more than $300 million for income generation credit and housing
credit (CCRD, 1997).
A
recent study by the World Bank examined the way in which four financial
institutions handled rural credit. The institutions were; Bank of Agriculture
and Agriculture Cooperative (BAAC - Thailand), Grameen Bank (Bangladesh), Badna
Kredit kecamatan (BKK- Indonesia) and Rakyat Indonesia Unit Desa Bank
(Indonesia) (Cameron, 1995). The following points emerge from the World Bank
study:
Interest
rate is not the most important feature of a rural credit scheme, availability of
fund being the most important factor.
It
is generally not true that low returns on borrowed funds are directly related to
high rates of interest. For example, the interest rate charged by BKK-Indonesia
was 42% with short-term retail credit to small rural businesses set at 130% per
year. By comparison rates in the organized money market at district level were
up to 48% per year. Grameen Bank of Bangladesh offers loans at 40% per year as
compared to the organized market with a rate of 48%. Despite these substantially
different policies, borrowers from both Banks are able to sue their credit
without difficulty.
Credit
extended at low rates of interest tended to be more harmful than helpful. Those
who borrow at low rates of interest, for example, 9% charged by BAAC-Thailand,
are able to invest in high risk or low returning projects and have often become
locked indebted cycle when the project fails. Providing credit at an interest
rate that covers cost or at a market level was recommended by the study as these
helps force borrowers to invest carefully in projects that are worthwhile. The
study also shows that extending cheap credit is not the most appropriate way to
help the rural poor.
Financial
institutions involved in rural credit are able to reduce their risk and refrain
from a strict collateral policy. Extending credit to small agricultural groups
who share the same social and economic status (personal and collective
assurances), provide a sense of ownership and leads to an understand that their
individual repayments are important to the collective success or failure of the
group.
The
word sustainability can be defined in different ways and has different meaning
depending on whether we are referring to the environment, resources,
institution, structure, process, skill or attitudes. And it also can be used
referring to goal, national organizational or programme levels.
Dale (1992:70) has defined the sustainability in the present context as
the prospect of maintenance after the programme period of the perspectives, the
types of organizational structures, and the work procedures developed or
promoted in the course of the programme period.
The
sustainability of the credit programme is a main factor to sustain the flow of
valued benefiting to its members or clients overtime. The sustainability of the
credit institutions is based on financial sustainability and institutional
sustainability. (Elaine and James, 1994) stated that, for reaching
sustainability, the central task in to establish a mature organization with a
programme that achieves impact at a reasonable scale of operation and viability.
Sustainable of small enterprise development organization can and must meet 100
percent auto-financing for their credit operations and establish a diversified
base for other operational expenses not directly linked to credit (Otero, 1994).
The
sustainability does not mean 100 percent self-sufficiency in all programme
aspects. Some other activities such as training, business services may continue
to require a subsidy. In this aspect, Otero (1994) determined the sustainability
as the ability to generate resources on favorable terms from diversified,
reliable set of resources. This includes local fund-raising from private and
government sources, fun-raising form external donors and internal income
generation from interest, other client fees and savings.
Financial
self-sufficiency is a prerequisite for making financial services widely
available to micro-enterprises. Yet debate continue on whether it is feasible
for most institutions. A financial self-sufficient credit operation must cover
the following through fees and interest charges: operational cost, including
loan loss reserves; the cost of funds; and inflation (Otero, 1994).
The
factor for financial sustainability is the interest rate policy designed to
improve the credit system is to reduce transaction costs. A realistic rate of
interest can be set in terms of wider market rate. Credit agency will remain
non-viable if their costs are greater than the interest between borrowing and
lending.
The
real interest rate should be positive in order to sustain of the credit
agencies. If the real interest rate negative vitally makes the loan a gift from
lender to borrower (the latter pay back less in real terms than was borrowed).
The real interest negatives mean the agencies charge the subsidy interest rate.
Savings
mobilization is a component for the sustainability of the credit institutions.
Ellis (1992) states that the generation of funds from savers is considered as a
key feature of self-sustaining credit institutions. First, a strong savings base
reduces the reliance on external funding. Second, savers and borrowers are often
the same people at different points in time in the community, reducing the
information costs of transactions. Third, people tried to an institution for
both savings and borrowings are less likely to default on loans. Fourth, farmers
with savings can often self-finance small outlays so that loan became oriented
to bigger outlays with lower transaction costs per unit of money.
A
self-sustaining financial system requires an interest rate on loans sufficient
to cover the three components of (i) the interest rate paid to savers, (ii) the
average cost of making transactions, and (iii) a risk margin to cover the
probability of default (Ellis, 1992).
A
straightforward way to look at the financial sustainability of the savings and
credit operation is to look at its income compared to its costs (Havvers, 1996
as quoted by Johnson and Rogaly, 1997).
Sustainability index (SI) = Percentage of total cost cover by income
total income earn
from credit programme during the period
=
x 100
total credit
programme costs during period
The income received includes interest and fees on loans. Programme costs
include all staff, office, and other costs necessary to run the programmes.
Johnson and Rogaly (1997) concludes that financial sustainability is only
one component of ensuring that schemes are able to provide services in the long
term; aspects of management and organizational structure are equal critical. The
organizational form may be the most significant design element in relation to
long-term sustainability.
Rural Credit is considered as a major component for accelerating rural
economic growth in Cambodia. The commercial banking institutions are
non-existent in rural areas and the state-run provincial banking system with 21
branches is effectively moribund (Elizabeth and Mark, 1998:3). The absent of the
rural banking facilities and staff with experiences in the rural finance is one
of major constraints in agricultural development in Cambodia.
To
fill this gap, since 1991, government and non-governmental micro-credit
programmes have expanded rapidly in Cambodia. As of 1997, 85 organizations are
engaged in micro-credit programmes servings 170,000 families with total loan
disbursement about US$ 9 million. Through theses figures
appear impressive, this numbers present less than ten percent of the Cambodia
rural households (CCRD, 1997:10). Table 3.2 shows that ten major credit
operators including two programmes which cooperation with the government
agencies, PRASAC and MOWA/UNICEF, account for some 75% of the total reported
clients outreach and the top six operators account for more than 66 percent of
the total outstanding loans.
Table
3.2 Performance of Selected Credit Operators
as of 31 December, 1997
Operator |
Number of clients |
% to total |
Outstanding loans |
% to total |
PRASAC |
47,454 |
21.09 |
1,970,004 |
13.14 |
MOWA/Unicef |
19,398 |
8.63 |
460,501 |
3.07 |
ACLEDA |
45,498 |
20.23 |
6,130,771 |
40.88 |
GRET/EMT |
28,597 |
12.71 |
796,512 |
5.31 |
Sielaniti |
5,637 |
2.51 |
247,444 |
1.65 |
WRI/CCB |
8,144 |
3.61 |
162,744 |
1.09 |
CRS |
5,153 |
2.29 |
226,571 |
1.51 |
ANS |
3,007 |
1.34 |
n.a |
n.a |
Hatta
Kaekar |
1,694 |
.76 |
n.a |
n.a |
CONCERN |
2,400 |
1.07 |
n.a |
n.a |
Sub-Total |
166,952 |
74.20 |
9,994,547 |
66.65 |
All
others |
58,048 |
25.80 |
5,005,453 |
33.35 |
Total |
225,000 |
100.00 |
15,000,000 |
100.00 |
Source:
(Abrera and Pierce, 1998)
The
need for rural credit in Cambodia is demonstrated by the existence of a
widespread informal credit market and by the high rates of interest charged, of
the order of 20-30 percent per month. Within agricultural loans in kind in the
form of fertilizer generally demand repayment is double of the value at the end
of 3-4 months period, equivalent to 20-25 percent monthly rate. The survey of 11
villages by UNICEF in 1994 revealed that 40-50 percent of farm families were
indebted (Ministry of Planning, 1995).
The
study conducted by the ministry of Rural Development through the CCRD in 1994
found that 60% of the rural people need the access to credit. Credit needs are
therefore substitute for exploitative consumption loans to cover household rice
deficits as well as to facilitate and improve rice production and yields by
providing fertilizer and seed, which will help to provide food security among
poverty groups and to provide more productive, sustainable farm households.
Loans are further need for income diversification through small-scale and
non-farmer activities.
The
rural credit in Cambodia are served both the traditional informal lenders
(composes of moneylenders, traders, and suppliers) and the GO and NGO credit
operators. The informal lenders can provide only the short-term loan period,
which charge high interest rate, typically from 15% to 30% per month. But, the
GO and NGO credit operators can provide short-term and long-term period with the
interest rate range from 1% to 6% per month (it depends on the kind of the
operators). Loans used by the rural people in different purposes, improving
agricultural investment and additional investments. The report of socio-economic
survey made by the student with organizing by the Credit Committee for Rural
Development found that the people need credit very much for purchasing
fertilizer, work cattle, water pump and extending their business etc.
The
credit operators are very active in micro-enterprise lending and some of them
are planned to provide larger loan in the rural areas. NGO position paper, 1996
divided three types of credit programmes implementing in Cambodia namely:
Community-based credit and savings project.
Theses project establishes village level credit and saving associations more
popularly known as "Village bank." The village bank provide an
opportunity for the members to use internally generated funds, coming chiefly
from mobilized savings.
Community development project with credit component.
There are NGOs implemented community development projects that integrate credit
services with other community development components such as health, literacy,
human rights, etc. This are not designed to support credit delivery in long
term.
Non-bank micro-finance organizations.
There are donors support NGO credit and saving programmes, which focus on the
creation of viable and sustainable micro finance institutions. The long-term
goal is to transform them into full banking micro-finance institutions that have
the capacity to intermediate deposits.
Based
on the experiences of credit operators in Cambodia since 1988, the methodology
has been used is similar to micro-credit operators in the other developing
countries, particularly the Grameen Bank of Bangladesh model. The methodology is
based on people's participation and uses the following models (Cameron, 1995):
Solidarity group/loan group.
There are self-selected groups of from five to seven people, usually with not
more than two from the same household. Loan are generally for individual
purposes but group activities are also financed and all members to the group
guarantee the loan on the basis that default by the borrower prevents any other
group members from borrowing and graduated penalties are applied to the
defaulters.
Village group:
Five to seven loan groups come together to form a village bank, with the village
bank having he responsibility of loan appraisal and approval, disbursements,
collection of repayments, collection of savings as well as administration. The
management of each village bank is vested in committee, the most successful
being elected rather than appointed.
Implementing organization:
(Implementer). There are either a local NGOs and international NGOs and at least
in the early stages, have provided the village bank's capital either directly or
as an agents or implementor for an international NGOs or a sources of funds made
available under a bilateral arrangement. The implementer provides training to
the village group on programme implementation and training on basic management
including that loan portfolio.
In
Cambodia, the predominant lending methodology is village banking model, but
incorporating group lending. The village bank includes typically 7 to 9 groups,
about 35 to 50 persons. Group leaders or all the members elect a chairman,
treasurer who control the finances, and a secretary who undertake the
bookkeeping. The average loan size is US$ 25 to US$ 60, with an average loan
period of 4 - 10 months.
All
of the credit operators in Cambodia are based on the grand from various
bilateral and multilateral donor agencies. The grant support directly through
the government and non-governmental Organizations. The main donors are
supporting the financial sector in Cambodia are: Asian Development Bank (ADB),
Caisse Francaise de Development (CFD), the European Union, UNDP/ILO, UNICEF,
USAID and others small donors. The study conducted by Elizabeth and Mark stated
that the donor communities have been influential both in the design and the pace
of development micro-finance sector in Cambodia. The donors support also reflect
their own policy objectives, since the local people still limited knowledge and
experiences in implementing rural credit programmes.
Ministry
of Planning, 1995 identified some problems related to the rural credit operating
in Cambodia as the followings:
The
common practice has been to provide below-cost delivery of funds. However, full
cost coverage is a minimum condition for the full maintenance of a revolving
fund and thus for the sustainability of a particular programme. It is therefore
a requirement even where the programme is directed towards poverty groups. Costs
to be covered include interest paid on project funds received, if any; the cost
of all personnel and equipment involved in administration and loan supervision,
including field visits; and losses through defaults. At the same time, real
interest charges need to be calculated over and above the rate of inflation;
and, if the fund is to expand in order to increase the number of beneficiaries
over time, interest charges need to be further increased.
Factors
which have underline the practice of below-cost charging include:
A
lack of understanding of the sustainability requirement because of concern for
delivery to poor groups;
Differences
in loan conditions imposed by external agencies and separate remuneration of NGO
staff time, such that certain categories of cost are hidden and less likely to
be reflected in the rates of interest applies; and
Variation
in the cost structure associated alternative systems of loan delivery and
supervision in different kinds of scheme.
Partly
related to the above, wide variation has existed in the interest rates charged
to similar clients, from 1 percent up to 18 percent per annum. This implies
inequity and inefficiency in the market for loan funds in that similar borrowers
pay different interest rates according to the organization from which they
borrow and possibly, the clients' locations.
Because
of the increasing volume of loan funds distributed through NGOs, there are some
concerns over macroeconomic control and possible inflationary impacts.
The
focus of direct assistance to the poor and on micro-enterprises has been
valuable and evidently, but might also divert attention form the wider problems
of credit as well as from areas of credit which could have indirect but
important positive impacts on the rural and urban poor. Credit for private
sector trade - for instance, to stock fertilizers and other inputs in rural
trading centers and making these much more readily available - could benefit
poor farmers by increasing farm yields and farm households sustainability.
Lastly,
the situation under which NGO micro-credit agencies are operating as financial
institutions outside any formal legal framework is clearly unsatisfactory if
they are to continue to play and important and increasing role in different
sectors of the economy.
Some weaknesses on experiences of micro-finance implementing in Cambodia
which identified by (CCRD, 1997) as the followings:
·
It is not clear about who is
the owner of capital
·
It is not financial
self-sufficient
·
It depends upon the foreign aid
fully
·
Activities do not reach to the
more remote rural area
·
Credit activities are allocated
in many places, but with limited clients
·
Credit for the poor is very
small if compared to the more capable businessman. In short, it varies form the
conception of helping the poor farmers.
·
Weak of
interest in savings mobilization