WELCOME TO YOU ALL!

The essay takes the phenomenon of ethnic mobilisation in account. Enjoy! 
 
 

ABSTRACT

The Splits and Tugs of Indian Society. An Account of the Features in Indian Society which have, so far, Stabilised the Ethnic Conflict-Ridden Country.
   by Hansi Elsbacher, B.A.
 

   This essay modifies the competition model of ethnic mobilisation, in that it tries to point out the necessity in distinguishing between mobilisation of ethnic or social movements and the outright, often armed fight for the establishment of political or geographical independence. The case studies have been the last decade’s ethnic movements arising on the Indian subcontinent, all of them not exactly fitting in the stereotype of what may count as an ethnic movement. Actually, such talk is part of the rhetoric pervading the arena of social conflict, and serves to legitimate or to delegitimise the mobilisation of other groups. This rhetoric is to be taken ernestly, since it is in the discrediting of neighbouring ethnies, that the own one is formed, the history and the culture determine along which lines the ethnic recruitment will take place. The structures of Indian society that have developed throughout the ages serve mainly to stabilise, and it is in the imbalance of these that a crumbling of the Indian Union may become real.
 

The splits and tugs of Indian society
„To awaken history was to cease to live instinctively. It was to begin to see oneself and one’s group the way the outside world saw one; and it was to know a kind of rage. India was now full of this rage. There had been a general awakening. But everyone awakened first to his own group or community; every group thought itself unique in its awakening; and every group sought to separate its rage from the rage of the other groups.“
950321
1 Introduction
 The post-cold war paradigm of international politics is yet to take form but two trends can already be noted. One, it seems as if international politics are being increasingly intertwined with economy.  Two, since the fall of the iron curtain and the crumbling of the Eastern Bloc/the Soviet Union/the Warsaw Pact and an end (?) to bloc politics, ethnic sentiments are catching power. At least, these are the ways in which politics today seem to be treated.
 In many parts of the Third World, economic growth is rapid and markets open up to foreign capital. The question posed by some has been: Do opened-up markets create ethnic conflict? In many cases this has been answered with a yes. The competition model attempts to describe how.
 I will try to elaborate on this theory about ethnic conflict, by applying it to the Indian scenario. India has been chosen because economic growth is rapid and the economy has been protected by the government. This should make for a clearcut verification of the competition model’s theses. India is distinguished from other countries by two features; the caste-system which more than social hierarchies in many other countries, I believe, regulates social transformation, and an attempt by the State to incorporate different ethnic minorities and overbridge the historical cleft between the Hindu majority and the largest minority, the Muslims, by means of secularism. The questions I will try to answer are the following. Have the reforms of the Indian economy brought about ethnic conflict? and if so, how? If not, which features of Indian society work stabilisingly? How do the State and society quell uprisings? And how does the way an ethnic group mobilises influence how much popular support it is to get, hence how successful it is to be? Finally, how do ethnic movements influence another? Is the way an ethnic group mobilises arbitrary or can the marks of identification and recruitment (language, skin colour etc) be traced to the surroundings in which it exists?
 My case studies are the recent ethnic mobilisations and/or outbreaks of separatist violence in four parts of the nation: Kashmir, the Punjab, the Hindu Heartland, and in Tamil Nadu. The way India works to stabilise unrest and the way the movements influence each other are being treated mainly at a macro, sometimes meso, level, i.e. the focus will be on the State (like in the cas of the term g/Government with a capital S in order to distinguish it from the lower levels of the Union) whose aim it is to maintain stability and ethnic, and therefore social, movements as actors with their own interest in achieving independence in one form or another. In the final chapter, I return to the competition model in order to modify its theses.

2 Methodology.
 The competition model is a primordialist view of ethnic conflict developed by Barth and others, which claims that the competition for resources always constitutes the underlying reason for ethnic, and therefore social, conflict. It draws on the rationalist school of thought, and has been developed and extended through the past two or three decades.
 Max Weber, the German sociologist, in Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft (Economy and Society) stressed the importance of that movements such as ethnic ones are based on a constructed, not objective, reality as perceived by the groups mobilising. The belief, which I call subjective, that an ethnic group has certain common points of reference or features on which identity, therefore exclusion of others, has been retained in the competition model. I will try below to try to show that these marks of identification are determined by the competing ethnic groups in particular, and society in general. In this, the history of ethnic animosities plays a significant role in that it emphasises traditional splits and divisions, therefore also the possible marks of identification.
 Frederick Bart, a norwegian sociologist, contributed to the theory mainly by his concentrating on boundaries.  In the rationalist school of thought, the number or the amount of possible boundaries should be determining factors as regards both ethnic identification and possibly also as regards the ethnic group’s success in achieving independence from the nation-state to which they „belong“.
 In its most recent form, Olzak and Nagel claim that modernisation like industrialisation, urbanisation, and an increase in the number and extent of opportunities to compete and organise politically make up the main conditions for what they call ethnic mobilisation.  Industrialisation increases the inter-ethnic competition for jobs and wages, through modernisation. Further up the road, we can add other collective resources like education, housing etc. With modernisation follows migration and urbanisation. With increased inter-ethnic contact, members of different ethnic groups realise their membership, which may have so far been hidden to them. Networks of contact, for instance, serve firstly to gain competitive advantages in the hunt for these collective resources , and secondly, to increase ethnic identification as well as distinguishing one ethnie from the other ones. In Olzak and Nagel’s words, the ethnic boundaries get activated.
 Increased scales of organisation help mobilise the larger groups, at the expense of smaller ones. The smaller get incorporated with the larger groups. Increased chances of cooptation of interests therefore should help ignite mobilisation.
Expansion of the secondary and tertiary sectors of the economy increase urbanisation and set an end to the segregation of labour markets, thus increase competition.
Expansion of the political sector ignites ethnic mobilisation by introducing ethnic questions into politics.
Supranational organisations take away power from the state level, by giving it to ethnic minorities.

 „(T)he presumed consolidating processes of state- and nationbuilding rest upon the same ideological base as a launching point for subnationalism - that of self-determination.“

 Ethnicity is consequently to be seen chiefly as an instrument, the use of which may provide members of the ethnic group in question (perhaps only a few of them) with rewards like surplus value, jobs, education, social benefits et cetera.
 Some nation-states have more of a pluralist character than others do. The more ethnicly homogenous or segregated the society is, the less danger will there be that ethnic conflict gets ignited.  In a country which consists of many different minorities, the threat of conflict will always be existing. Particularly so in times of modernisation and deregulation of segregated markets.
„For conflict to be widespread and intense, it must be social rather than interpersonal...“
 It follows that ethnic mobilisation is a social movement depending on increased interethnic contact.

 According to the Split Market Theory, developed a.o. by Michael Hechter, the existence of segregated markets of labour hinders the outbreak of ethnic mobilisation.  When the borders between segregated markets then dissolve, interethnic competition will call for mobilisation.
 This leads us to the role of the state. At the interior level, this is a stabilising one. All regimes have reasons to defend stability. Turmoil only makes foreign investment impossible and financial planning difficult, and certainly no Government wants to give away regions which are lucrative from a budgetary point of view.
 Internal colonialism refers to the state of affairs, when one part of the country (usually the centre) is accused by another (the periphery) of an extraction of the surplus values extracted in that region. As we will see later, this is a regular topic in the recruitment of members (perhaps in the strength of) for one ethnic group, and in their identification (i.e. their prospects of in-group unity).
 A definition of how exactly mobilisation develops, is only vaguely hinted at by the authors, apart from the so-called activation of boundaries which are seen as largely fluid. If it isn’t accordingly defined, there will be no way of distinguishing between the different stages of ethnic mobilisation. Because of this, I will suggest that mobilisation could be seen as a first step in the fight for independence from a larger state, a discoursive step, rather than one signified by concrete acts of violence a.s.o. These may come later, as a second step, but will always be preceded in a change of discourse in the direction of a more ethnocentric view of the own culture, at the expense of the competing ones or the „state ideology“.
 The advantages arising out of this are firstly that movements which haven’t become violent, still can be seen as mobilising. The mobilisation, the transformation of discourse through identification or ethnocentrism, and the continued armed fight for independence, will thus be given a continuous pattern of transformation, usable for further research on the topic. By either chopping up the path towards separatism, or by seeing it as a continuum, it would be possible to examine both the synchronic and the diachronic aspects of how ethnic mobilisation and separatism work. Secondly, this also gives us the option to compare ethnic with other forms of social conflict, like the oppression by the majority of one or many of the minorities or, in everyday language „nationalism“ or „racism“. Here, the term race will be replaced by ethnicism on the grounds of skin colour, and nationalism and „nation“ seen as sentiments for one cultural nation, one ethnie that is, without paying respect to whether this ethnie has the status of majority (i.e. backed by a national Government) or not, in which case it is a minority which may challenge the nation-state.  Thirdly, it will give us the chance to crystallise the competition model, and to clarify some of the ambiguities present in the non-distinction between mobilisation and actual and outright fighting for separatism and/or independence.
 In the latter case, the claims for a separate piece of land will have to be replaced by for instance increased shares of job and education quotas or higher salaries a.s.o., but the question of how social mobilisation based on ethnic identification develops will nevertheless be clarified.
 Susan Olzak  means that the framework of competition theory accent the changing economic and political rankings and strategies favouring ethnic mobilisation over other possible ones. It will however not explain to us under what immediate circumstances mobilisation arises. By this I mean where the border between mobilisation and non-mobilisation is drawn, or for that matter when mobilisation turns violent.
 This is difficult, since the reasons for ethnic mobilisation are subjective. It is, like Bèlanger and Pinard and others point out, only when one group perceives itself as being unfairly treated, that they mobilise.  The link between the mobiliser’s arguments and actual reality is rather arbitrary, or like Olzak and Nagel put it:
   „...ethnicity (is)...relational and partly volitional.“
 How then can we causally link modernisation with ethnic mobilisation and violence? Fact is, without more careful scrutiny, we can’t. The collapse of segregated markets and ethnic mobilisation may only be simultaneous in time. Switzerland is mentioned as a telling example, where many different ethnic minorities live peacefully together.  Here, the role of the state and its consociational politics is at work in combination with a slow and steady growth of the economy. But if one ethnic group managed to establish independence, would not the other groups follow even in Switzerland? Modernisation therefore sets the stage for likely ethnic mobilisation. If, and to what extent, ethnic uprising occurs is largely in the hands of the state and society.
 My aim is to try to develop this argument further, using examples of Indian ethnic mobilisation, violence, and conflict during the past decade - before and after the reinitiation of the reforms of the economy - in order to see the connection reforms and ethnic conflict may have.  I will pay particular respect to the Indian state’s efforts and strategies to incorporate ethnic minorities both by the use of secularism and to quench social uprising by the use of force. We will see that Indian society is divided along centre-peripheral lines,  which could seem to make political cooptation and therefore success in separatism easy. But it is also bound together by various networks, which account for interdependence and stability. The distinction between mobilisation and violent uprising, which is missing in the competition model as developed so far, is vital in studying the differences between different ethnic movements in India, and it is, as will become clear in this essay, crucial for studying the role of the State in ethnic conflict.

3. The mobilisation of ethnic movements in India
 The competition model does not verify what mobilisation actually is. The hint that is given, is that the borders between ethnic groups, which are seen as largely fluid, get strengthened at this stage. Mobilisation is opposed to assimilation with the nation-state or the demos, the people, and is hence an increased awareness of the factors distinguishing and therefore uniting one ethnie or ethnic group.
 I would add that it is carried out by a change in discourse, an exchange from emphasising nation- to group identification.  In Kashmir this would mean that those mobilising are those who mentally and culturally give up their identity as Indian in favour of their being Kashmiri. This change in discourse serves firstly to recruit and to create unity among the group members and secondly (and as a consequence of this) to distinguish the group from other competing ones.  The way from mobilisation can therefore be seen as a continuum through which ethnocentric views are expressed and tolerated increasingly often. Following Heckmann ethnic mobilisation is a normal form of socialisation, that more often than not goes on in every society and culture. It goes without saying, that an upgrading of the own ethnic group and the rejection of other groups, go hand in hand.
 „Instead of identity being defined by a sense of belongingness(sic!) and solidarity arising out of shared life-worlds, it becomes focused on opposition to an Other: the „We“ is defined not by reference to a framework of shared experiences...but by the negation of the Other.“

 In this sense ethnicism is not just subjective, but also relative to its surroundings in that the way an ethnie mobilises will depend on how its members can both identify with the group and distinguish themselves from other, „competing“, groups. The mark of identification (language, history, religion etc.) should further have some effect on the recruitment of members, hence the popular support it can gather, implicitly seen in how successful it will be. But in this respect, ethnicism isn’t subjective at all. It is instead aimed at creating unity among the group members and excluding others from it. History, competing groups, and the surroundings - a.o. the State - determine whether it will draw on skin colour, religion, language, or historical sentiments etc.
 

 What I call the second step is the outbreak of violence in an armed fight for independence. Of course, there may be in-betweens, like political organisation (like Olzak and Nagel claim), demonstrations etc. But when all comes round, an ethnic group is an ethnic group only as long as it seeks independence from the Government of the nation-state (here the area administered by and under the jurisdiction of the national Government) they „belong to“. This independence is to be seen as both geographical and political. That is, it includes both claims for a separate homeland and political freedom or independence for the group (c.f. positive freedom from exterior restraints - and negative freedom to do something). The Hindu nationalist movement, even if violently purging Muslims, had claims to increased independence, really increased economic and political power, for its members. Being the ethnic group in majority, they cannot lay claims to a separate homeland. To do this, they need to take to ethnic cleansing, as which the riots can be seen.
 If the ethnic group can go through the legitimate and established political channels it will not be an ethnic movement anymore. Here I differ from the competition model’s advocates. More often, the opposite is the case as seen below.
 Since my definition of mobilisation as a change in discourse could comprise almost all different ethnies in any country, it is not very useful for research. My object of study must therefore be the second step, the armed fight for independence.
 Two of my case studies will be the Punjab and Kashmir. These have been chosen because they have transcended to violence, they occurred nearly simultaneously, and they challenge not only stability, but also the Hindu majority’s religious grip on power. In order to set these in perspective, I will compare them with the rightwing Hinduism, erupting after the initiation of reforms, having no claims for a separate homeland (a semi-ethnic movement?) and challenging secularism (indicative of a split of the centre?). My fourth object of study is one ethnic movement, which hasn’t (yet) resorted to violence, and therefore within my definition, has only mobilised, not taken the second step. It differs from the others in that it is situated mainly in the south (where ethnic animosities have been scarce lately, whereas before independence from the north was a feature). My intention is to compare these in order to see firstly the differences in the grounds of mobilisation/eruption of violence, which I see as determined by the surroundings, and possibly contributing to the success of a separatist movement, secondly how these instances of mobilisation or uprising may be related to each other and society, and thirdly to see how the Indian scenario differs from or verifies the competition model’s theses. All have to do with modernisation, and that is what one could expect the financial reforms to bring about.
 The reforms, brought about as parts of the structural adjustment demanded by international money lenders, can be seen as the expression of supranational organisations. The prime mover in India, I will claim, is not primarily the reforms as such, but the weakening of the State-level. In the next chapter I elaborate on this, reforms and the erosion of the Indian State-class.
 
 4.1 The State Class
 The Indian State defends stability, and central vested interest by means of a large bureaucratic elite. The nation-building Congress party was part of the Indian independence movement, and has been in power for most of the time since independence was granted in 1947. Their large administrative apparatus was inherited from the British, and it numbers up to 18 million state employees.  An Import Substitution Policy, which was started in 1957 was brought about by a lack of foreign currency. This aimed at national self-determination and industrial development in protection of Indian industrialists, employment, and the poor.  Industrial or technological stagnation occurred as a result of this. A licensing system for imports and production decided in five-year plans - or the License Permit Quota Raj as critics prefer to call it - was introduced and it gave rise to the increased power of the administration by their positions as rent-seekers extracting surplus values in a way that increases inefficiency and corruption in the state sector and as receivers of bribes and to the Congress party who, having governed the country for most of the time since independence, appoint these.

4.2. The centre
The state-class is a universal phenomenon and hard to define.  The denominations range from state-class through political hierarchy to establishment or social elite, or a combination of these. Who the members are, varies even more. I suggest that it is a structural power, not a concrete political body, which strives towards the centre. It has a stabilising role in guarding Indian secularism and therefore, as well as on the grounds of historical Hindu-Muslim animosities dating as far back as to the first millennia A.D., stability.  In India the centre variably includes members of Congress, the administration, parts of the middle to upper classes and castes, and more indirectly others. In brief, everyone with a temporal or permanent interest in protecting the „old“ Indian system and expressing it politically by uniting against peripheral uprisings or what they see as other „threats“.
 Being the defender of Indian unity, the centre further has to oppose the tugs from the periphery. All these challenge the reason why India is a nation. That reason is secularism, and part of what one might call „the state ideology“. Indians from the educated classes were early employed in the British colonial administration, and as a result administrators today come from the same sections of the population, which includes influential ethnic groups like the Sikhs and the Farsis.  Many have been employed in state-owned companies by means of connections, i.e. nepotism, or maybe even by heritage.  As protectors of stability, the members of the centre have previously had an interest in defending the Indian state’s secularism. The secularism of the Indian state differs from that of Western democracies, in which it mainly means a separation of the church from the state or vice versa. In India the principle of Sarva Dharma Samabhava - „equal respect for all religions“ is an intention to be able to incorporate believers of all different faiths, not putting the majority Hindus in an advantaged position. Historically, it has served to overbridge the gap between the Hindus, which account for 83% of the 929 million population and the largest minority group the Muslims, with 11%.  .
 „(T)he very idea that the State should become the defender of one religion, or one sect within a religion, was alien to the essence of Hinduism.“

4.3. The reforms and the erosion of the centre
 Until recently, the centre could be said to have held India in a firm grip (not without challenge of course) by the largesse of the state sector and the administration. One big part has been the Congress party. But today Congress is ridden by interior splits and personal mud-slinging and has been losing ground to other competitors since the 1980s. The weakening of Congress is often ascribed to Indira Gandhi, who in the eighties abolished in-party-democracy and introduced nepotist appointment of ministers etc. But the centre has, with different means, succeeded in keeping together the world’s second most populous country as well as managed to quell the world’s largest ethnic movement, the rightwing Hindu movement.  Before, Singh claims, India’s ethnic minorities have often allied with „secular Congress“ because they were minorities, not because of ideology.  If so, there should be a clear connection between the decline of Congress and increased ethnic instability. Most likely is that the two are mutually reinforcing.
 Congress and their administrators have lost a lot of ground to the Newly Rich Elite, the NRE, or the large and growing middle class at present consisting of about 250 million people.  These didn’t arise as a result of the recent reforms, but out of the import substition policy, which allowed a large number of small traders and craftsmen to set up their own business, without being challenged by large-scale industries, multinationals, and foreign competition.  The group therefore arose before the reforms of the economy were initiated. In the late eighties, the group numbered 180 million.  It is therefore reasonable to regard the reforms as not (yet) having negatively affected the size of this group.
 The end of the anti-multinational and protectionist policy was brought about in the late eighties, but the initiation of reforms (i.e. the deregulation of the licensing system for imports and production) was started by P.V. Narasimha Rao in 1991. This was largely because India - just like in 1957 - needed credit from the IMF and the World Bank. The budget deficit was large due to the fall of trading partner and military ally the Soviet Union, and left-out oil imports from Iraq due to UN-imposed sanctions during the Gulf War in the early 1990s. The conditions for credit liability were that India took measures against the tariff- and non-tariff trade barriers, the large budget deficit, the inflation, the huge state-sector and the corruption and inefficiency therein, and that the borders were opened up to foreign investment and free capital and market flows. In brief the reforms aim at deregulating government intervention in as many areas as possible of the economy.  Criticism of reforms in general has mainly come from outside the political establishment and opposition. Political parties seem convinced that reforms of the economy are good in nature and only spokesmen for various vested interests debate which sector to regulate next.
 The reforms have not brought about the arisal of the petit bourgeouis NRE group, but maybe challenged them.  Like in many other Asian economies, for instance China and Vietnam, the middle class has become a strong political and economic factor. Of course, Congress and the centre have lost a lot of support, mainly among the sections of the population who previously gained from their privileged positions as state-class members, but who have been able to make a fortune in one way or another, who now sympathise with other parties. A rightwing Hindu movement of middle-class supporters could be one possible consequence of this loss of power that the centre has suffered. But Shankar Jha points out, that this rightwing Hindu movement started before the reforms (in the early eighties), and that it probably stems or has caught speed from the Mandala problemacy, in which the middle to upper castes were involved. The Mandala question was that of whether the quotas for employment in the state sector should be reserved for the lower castes and the casteless (the OBCs, other backward castes), like the Janata Dal or National Front Government and its leader V.P. Singh claimed or whether the 27% of these jobs should be reserved for the poor (which would also include middle- to high-caste members), something which the middle to upper-caste student movement vehemently argued. This led to the resignation of that coalition Government, and possibly also to the strength of the middle-class supported rightwing Hinduism.
 Kolodner claims that this rightwing Hinduism may now have come to a halt.  Fact is, Congress has won back some of the states lost in elections a few years ago to the Bharathiya Janata Party, BJP, which was backed by the other groups in the rightwing Hindu movement and which makes up their political wing. But this seems a bit naive, since the history of India has been ridden with splits between Hindus and non-Hindus. I cannot see one single reason for why this is supposed to have come to a permanent end.
 Nevertheless, the centre has been weakened and secularism has begun to be seriously challenged by the middle class - a relatively new and influential group in Indian politics.

5. Centre versus priphery
 Not only the NRE challenges the centre. There are tugs in India between the rich and the poor sections of the population, between different regions, between rural and urban classes, between different political decision levels, and perhaps between the north and the south. But many of these seem dormant. At least they are not the conflict parameters in Indian society which ignite violence today. The main conflict parameter, I would say, is the centre versus periphery conflict in its essence. The different actors striving in one way or other to preserve the Union Government’s authority are opposed to the other, peripheral, groups who try to cooptate, mainly on an ethnic basis.  It is mainly because cooptation has failed, that India still is one.
 Lately, ethnic mobilisation has increased, especially since the mid-1980s, before the reforms to deregulate government intervention in the economy took speed. Even if the reforms and the arisal of rightwing Hinduism started simultaneously, they cannot be verified to be directly related. But since many things indicate an erosion of the centre - ethnic movements, a challenge from Hindus to secularism, a splitting up of Congress and a growing middle class a.s.o. - it seems tempting to try to set these in connection with another.
 Only increased ethnic competition for collective resources or urbanisation and political organisation doesn’t suffice for an explanation of why ethnic conflict arises. In the case of ethnic Hinduism, the direct link between ethnicism and prospective gains may be protruding, just like the competition modelists predict. But there are other explanations. The Saffron Resurgence, as the Hindu nationalist movement is also called, was preceded by protests, some of them violent, against the use of English or local languages beside Hindi, by the demonstrations against the Mandala job and education quotas, according to which more members of the lowers castes should be allowed to get employment and higher education, and also by an initially outspoken resistance by the BJP to an opening-up of trade and capital borders. In all this, the ethnocentric discourse of the Hindu movement was predominant. Shankar Jha means that the Saffron resurgence had tried to mobilise in this way years before the actual outbreak of violence. Like the competition modelists claim, when the segregation of markets gets overturned, ethnicism increasingly mobilises. It is important to set this in perspective to the splitting up of the centre, but it could also be a reaction against other ethnic uprisings in north India in the eighties. If the neighbouring group mobilises, insecurity will flourish and therefore prospects of recruitment, perhaps cooptation with the other mobilisers, will increase. Shankar Jha, Kolodner, and Gurharpal Singh all see ethnicism as a response to the efforts of Congress to keep the strength of the centre against the states, where other parties increasingly tend to obtain power. I suggest that even if increased ethnic competition may provide the basis for insecurity, ethnic „mobilisation“ (including the fight for independence) should in fact be seen as reactions to the centre’s and the rest of the periphery’s tugs, a joining-up for battle. One thing which speaks for this is that a change in the type of Government control executed and the taking of the second step, often seem to come together, which I will show, and the authors mentioned above claim. It is therefore vital for the ruption of ethnic violence that the State changes stance in controlling prospective sources of unrest.

5.1 Regulating stability from within.
 The centre takes measures against the periphery’s strains in protection of Indian unity, which relies on secularism of the state. Because of the nature of ethnic movements (they want to withdraw from the State), they have a peripheral role as opposed to the centre. Secularism is threatened by religious groups, and preferably by those who distinguish themselves from Hinduism. As seen above, the split between Muslims and Hindus has been existing since India’s period as a British colony and even resulted in the creation of Pakistan.  Hindu nationalism has existed in India at least since the 1870s.  Indian stability relies therefore mainly on a balance between the different religious camps (and the Hindu one). Cooptation among non-Hindu groups exerts a threat to the centre and the Hindu majority. The State’s or the centre’s strategy in this has been as follows:
 The Union Government has imposed central „President’s Rule“ and postponed elections to the state assembly in Punjab (President’s Rule was imposed and held between May 1987 and February 1992) as well as more recently in Kashmir, where the state governments had fallen into the hands of the opposition (read the periphery).
 In the Punjab, an anti-terrorist policy by means of legislation and reorganisation of security forces has helped the Union Government to keep the area in control.
 Also, the centre has revitalised the village council, the Panchayat Raj, in order to take away the power from the many opposition parties in various state governments, and give it to the poor.  The concept Panchayat Raj has been existing in India for centuries, and its first revitalisation (of the Ur-Panchayat in the early stages of the Indian independence movement against the British) was a brainchild of Mahatma Gandhi’s, and can therefore be said to apply to symbolic and historical sentiments among Indians.
 The centre has finally installed half a million Paramilitary Forces, responsible to the Union Government in New Delhi and not like the police to the state, in many areas of the nation, particularly where separatism might be a threat. The misnomer Border Security Forces is indicative of the fear that separatism comes from the periphery.  If it were directed against outside threats, the regular military forces would be strengthened, now these are complemented with forces which could in fact pose a threat to them. It is common in Inda, that new political bodies are created by the Centre in opposition to the periphery, when the old ones come to a standstill, and cannot function.

 Gurharpal Singh means that there are two ways which the centre uses to regulate stability; by hegemonic and violent control.
„(W)hereas violent control resembles overt domination, suppression, and open confrontation, hegemonic control combines Gramscian elements of coercion with some degree of consent.“
 Instances of violent control have been mentioned. To hegemonic control we can ascribe all politics executed culturally and politically by the Centre in order to create unity and consent with opposition, including various features of the Hindu culture and media, to which I will return.
5.2 Co-optation
 There are many tugs between different parts and groups in Indian society, and because of the federative character also between Union Government and the states. The Union Government, Congress, and the administration who make up the centre stand in opposition to the state governments of the Indian Union, which sometimes work centrifugally, i.e. with the periphery against the centre.  It is therefore very much up to ethnic movements in India to join sides with the state government in order to secure or obtain an increased degree of independence.
 If the ethnic movements, perhaps only a few of them and perhaps with other peripheral interests, were united against the centre their success would seem to be granted. But co-optation is made difficult not only because of the centre’s stabilising role, violent control, and so-far strong grip on power, but also because of systems of hierarchy, control, and dependence imposed on India, in other words the cultural hegemonic control. Three of the strongest of such systems are corruption, caste, and servant structures.

6. Corruption, caste, and servant structures as uniting features.
 What these have in common is that they are very hard to do anything about, because they tie up the majority of Indians with each other in systems of control, hierarchy, and interdependence. Only uppercaste Hindus benefit from the caste-system, but everyone in India is involved in it. Corruption, here mainly bribery, serves the same goal but accounts for an upward and centripetal distribution of income. Servant structures and the informal market are based in caste and account for the large informal sector, and distribution downwards through the caste system.
6.1. The caste system.
 The caste sytem was brought to India more than 4000 years ago by Indoaryan invaders from the north. The main caste groups are the Brahmins (Priests), Vaishiyas(Soldiers), Kshatriyas(Merchants etc.), and Sudras(Labourers etc.). Thousands of sub-groups or Jatis can be defined between the Brahmin priestly or intellectual caste, through public servants, merchants, traders, to the untouchables, the casteless, the Harijans, or the backward classes, as the denominations go for those below the caste system. In brief, it can be defined as an extremely rigid and conservative system preserving the hierarchical structure of society, not very different from the Confucian Chinese „Guanxi“ hierarchy according to which everyone in society stands in special relationship to each other, with the emperor as the man on top. By oppression of the darker skinned southern Dravidian peoples, the pale northerners who in general belong to the higher castes are favoured.  Uprisings have indeed occurred between these „races“, but been scarce lately.
 Physical contact and the sharing of food or water between people of different caste belongings are the media by which the taboos are broken, and those of the higher „rank“ so to speak could get befouled, and those of the lower rank could get punished, by law or by their Karma, their fate.
 Social immobility is non-existing within terms of caste, since caste also decides which job, education, or employment one is to have. In spite of the system being declared illegal many years ago and despite its being (at least openly) denunciated by many, it still holds human relations in India in a firm grip, especially in rural areas of the country. The labour markets are therefore segregated in India as in no other country.
 Every living individual, which includes animals as well as humans, might, according to the Hindu religion, be an incarnation (a rebirth) of any other deceased being. One’s deeds during one lifecycle or rebirth, make for which position one is to get in the next one. If one’s deeds are at the end of one lifecycle pure and good according to Hindu prescriptions, one will climb the ladder towards exclusion from life and rebirth, which is pain, and finally reach the state of nirvana, which means an end to pain and exclusion from the cycles of reincarnation. If the deeds are found to be less good however, one descends to suffer one more rebirth as a member of a lower caste, an individual hampered with misfortune, a sick person, or a woman. In this life, change is as good as impossible.
 Stability is - however unfair this might sound - one result of the caste-system. It is an ultimate tool for keeping society stable, people dependent on each other, and the masses in control. The caste system is both hierarchical and communalistic and it involves and decides the occupation and place in society for everyone, even if this is changing in urban, modernised, areas. A great deal of the Indian State’s secularism can be derived from the communalism in the Hindu caste system. The nearly complete absence of class-based animosities in India can be deduced from the strength and intensity with which caste and other structures operate on Indian society.

6.2. Corruption and nepotism
 Even if the caste-system has been outlawed for many years, it still holds India in its firm grip, and it is generally seen as „bad“. This is true for corruption as well. Not many would dare deny that corruption is inherent in the present structure of Indian society.
 Bribes in India are paid by the public to get the public sector work, and to cut down inefficiency and delays in all sorts of errands. The public servants of lower position are those who receive the bribes, and upward these through the hierarchy in a pyramidal fashion.  Many depend on this distribution of finances; families, friends, low-paid state-employees etc.
 In the end poverty and a very inequal distribution of income contribute and add to that many people in India make a living out of corruption.
 The import substitution policy and an unagile import licensing system may have reinforced the extent of corruption. Baksheesh however, the Indian language expression for bribery, indicates its very likely existence before the arrival of the Europeans. The existence of an old, rigid, inefficient, and much-embracing state bureaucracy may both be a cause and a result of bribery.

6.3. The servant structures
 The inefficiency and corruption in the state-sector, as well as in Indian society in general, make all errands time-consuming. Everyone with a more or less regular income has in fact to employ servants. Many have several ones. The caste the servant belongs to decides which occupation he or she is to have. A normal household may have a washerman or a Dhobi, someone who buys groceries, a handyman, and one or more chefs. All depend on the income from those in the family who lift regular salaries. Those who are poor and cannot afford servants, make use of the large informal sector. Of the locals that is, who offer primary and secondary goods and such services at low cost. In connection with the vocational immobility imposed by the caste-system, servant structures have a stabilising effect on Indian society by tying up different groups of the population with each other.
 India is, to sum-up, a stable continent partly because of corruption, nepotism, and servant structures which make a large number of people (rich and poor alike), and thereby very much the system itself, dependent on other parts of society. At a higher level, internal colonialism makes for a similar sort of interdependence between different parts of the country. At the lower level, the hegemonic control of the centre and its option to use violent control have made for balance.
6.4 Sum-up
 The existence of the state-class or the centre may be both a consequence of and a reason for these inextricably linked and mutually reinforcing phenomena. The caste-system has given rise to and reinforces social hierarchy, dependence on servant structures, and social immobility. Stability is a result, and the centre does both benefit from this system and reinforce it in order to stay in power.
 With the reforms, the erosion of and challenges to the centre have begun. The reformers have started to deregulate State intervention but not been able to abolish State employees’ and workers’ secured positions (they cannot lawfully be fired), corruption, nepotism, the servant structures, the existence of a large informal market, and inefficiency in Government enterprises and in the administration.
 As long as caste, corruption, and servant structures have their firm grip on India and puts her population in mutual dependence on each other, the peripheral, also the ethnic, groups cannot successfully co-optate. Neither the political opposition’s constant anguished cries about corruption, nor laws against the usage of caste have been efficient in toppling the caste-imposed or -inforcing hierarchies.
 Thus, we have once again confronted the chicken-or-egg-type question; Which of these phenomena reinforces the others? It would be appropriate to argue that these systems together impose certain structures on Indian society, which live lives on their own. If one of the components is swept away, the others will remain and if these keep the structures of dependence alive, balance will not be challenged. Ethnic uprisings will therefore as long as this dependence and control-system exists fail, because of divided loyalties and a lack of popular support.
 Further, the caste system has made for segregated labour markets, particularly in rural areas, where most of the population lives. This has, until now, largely hindered ethnic separatism in India.

7. Outbreaks of ethnic separatism in Kashmir, Punjab and doubtful ones in Tamil Nadu and the Hindu Heartland.
 Even so, there have been outbreaks of separatism, mainly in the North during the past twenty years or so. As already mentioned, mobilisation cannot be easily measured, so we have to focus on the second step, the outbreaks of violence. What is it, that has made for their success/failure? How did they arise? And can their development be related to any of the competition model’s hypotheses?
Kashmir
 The outbreak of separatism in Kashmir in 1987 followed accusations of centrally rigged state assembly elections, the cancelling of these, and the subsequent imposition of central rule on Kashmir by the Union Government. Kashmir’s mobilisation and the early armed fight for independence were carried out with claims for a homeland in a Muslim militant fashion. Today the movement’s previous pan-Islamic image seems to have faded and left the stage for interior splits between the different groups involved in the militant Jammu and Kashmir Liberation Front, the JKLF, and the political All-Party Hurriyat Conference, which comprises 32 parties.  At present the talks between the Union Government in New Delhi and the split-up separatist movement have come to a halt. Some of the groups fight for separatism, some want an annexation to Pakistan, and one guerrilla group  supports a continued membership of the Indian union.
 Increased competition may have been vital in spurring this movement, not as a result of reforms of the economy, which were initiated earlier than the outbreak of separatism, but maybe as a result of increased tourism in the area; a source for the highly valued and deeply appreciated foreign currency. Urbanisation was not directly necessary for the Kashmiris to mobilise.
 Kashmiri history is very much the history of Indian secularism. About 80% of the population of 3,2 million are muslims. Even though political tugs between the state and the centre have always been fought, predominantly about the degree of independence as regulated in article 370 of the Indian constitution. India’s Constituent Assembly had adopted this article shortly after independence in 1949. The article states, that it can only be amended by the Kashmir Constituent Assembly, which was dissolved in 1956.  Herein lies the trouble. Kashmir’s specific status within the Indian constitution cannot legally be altered, and this has - in the long run - contributed to the eruption of violence.
 Societal structures of dependence in all India and religious diversity in the group may have contributed to quench the uprising, as well as the immense number of army and paramilitary troops set in by the Union Government. But where political negotiations between the Union Government and the state come to a standstill, ethnic violence erupts. It is therefore in this case not increased scales of political organisation that contribute to ethnic violence, but a standstill in the opportunities to work politically. Increased scales of organisation may, like the competitionists claim, help in the discoursive mobilisation of ethnic movements.
 The Punjab
 In the Punjab, the 1984 occupation of the holy Golden Temple in Amritsar by the separatist group fighting for an independent Sikh nation, Khalistan, was demolished by Indian Government troops (operation Bluestar). Since then about 30,000 people have been killed.  This conflict started in 1984, so economic reforms (which were intiated later) cannot be blamed for the uprising.
„...where ethnic groups have contested, often violently, the nature of hegemonic control, the Indian (S)tate has resorted to violent control.“
 The Sikhs are distinct as a group and ethnically aware, and Sikhism is nothing new to India - it has been around at least since the late 19th century.
 Many Sikhs are, like Kashmiris, closely linked with the political establishment and many of them are successful traders or have positions in the police and the armed forces.  Therefore they have much to lose in uprising and separatism. Both Sikhs and Kashmiris have claims for a separate homeland. The Sikhs have a common culture and a more homogenous religion and a longer history (all important grounds of identification, recruitment and untiy) to a larger extent than do the Kashmiris, and neither of the movements has mobilised in a predominantly urban area.
 The Sikhs are influential and organised politically. According to the competition model chances of political organisation increase the risk or chance of ethnic mobilisation. But at the same time, the members of the ethnic group must not be too linked up with the social or political establishment. Then they have no reason for mobilisation. The case in the Punjab, according to Singh, differs from this part of the competition model, which may only be applicable to new or emergent ethnic groups. There, similar to Kashmir, the local, ethnic, party changed stance versus the Union Government in the early eighties.
„...the Punjab unit of the Congress Party...has historically accomodated Sikh political groups, provided they were prepared to forgo ethnic demands. Since 1967 (!) the efforts of Akali Dal to challenge hegemonic control have led to a campaign for autonomy...“
 This campaign for autonomy led to a reaction from the centre to implement an anti-terrorist policy with anti-terrorist legislation, a reorganisation of the state’s security apparatus, imposing President’s rule, and the cancelling of state elections.
 The Indian Union Government (the centre) and the separatists in the Akali Dal, the political party which during the fight for geographical independence split up into several smaller fractions, came on a crash course. Who bears the blame for this? Indira and Rajiv Gandhi some claim, since they were the first to use President’s rule, a induced by the fear of ethnic disintegration of the country.

 Tamil Nadu
 In Tamil Nadu, mobilisation is going on, but no violence has as yet erupted,  partly because of the lack of a uniting and distinguishing religion. The Tamils have a common culture, a longer historical heritage, a historical homeland, traditions of anti-Brahmin sentiments and different skin colour and caste membership than the others, but still.
 India Today of November 15, 1995, claims that Tamil Nadu is witnessing a resurgence of pro-Eelam (the Tamil homeland in Sri Lanka) sentiment. Pro-Eelam parties have arranged fasts, made resolutions for this Tamil homeland. But this is a protest against the Sri Lankan Government’s offensive against the Tamil Tigers. Miss Jayalalitha, Chief Minister of Tamil Nadu, hasn’t taken a strong stand against LTTE sympathisers in the state, the Union Government has declared. But the military has been present in the state.  Even so, it is difficult to tell how strained relations really are. Congress has never been strong in Tamil Nadu, and they continuously utter suspicions about international conspiracies among troubled areas. Both Punjab and Tamil Nadu (and the LTTE by their Government) have been accused of being supported by Pakistani and/or Chinese militants.  In Tamil Nadu, this can be part of the preparation for the introduction of violent control.
 Closely connected with the Tamil question is that of a north-south divide in India. Today the southern states Tamil Nadu and Kerala are very wealthy as compared with much of the north. The north depends financially on the south to a much larger extent than vice versa, it is a clearcut example of internal colonialism. But so is the case in Kashmir, where tourism has made for increased wealth, and the Punjab, where economic growth followed the land reforms of the so-called Green revolution.  Internal colonialism and unemployment is to my knowledge claimed to be the reason for all ethnic mobilisation everywhere. In Tamil Nadu however, as in the south, growth has been slow but steady. Why there has been no split between the northern Indoaryans and the southern Dravidians, who distinguish themselves from the Northerners in many ways, can also be traced to violent control. Especially since the Liberation Tigers of Tamil Eelam, the LTTE, fighting for a Tamil homeland for the ethnic minority on the Jaffna peninsula in the north and in the eastern parts of the island, were discovered to operate training camps in Tamil Nadu. Hegemonic control, because of strains between Congress and the AIADMK government of the state as well as interdependence-imposing structural features of society like the caste-system, corruption, and servancy may be present.
 Ethnic mobilisation and violence has been far more common in the North than in the southern parts of the country. One reason for this may be the longer period of unity in the south. The invasions from the North in earlier days were frequent and rarely reached the southern parts of the country.  Slow economic growth may have made for a smooth transition across a possible critical point of ethnic violence. Further the historical absence of ethnic uprising in the South has so far, calmed this part of the country. It takes a lot to be the first one out on a separatist mission. With improved communication channels, ethnicism may become more geographically independent.

Hindu Nationalism
 A Hindu nationalist movement - the Saffron Resurgence - backed by the BJP, the Bharathiya Janata Party and various organisations like Shiv Sena, the Vishwa Hindu Parishad, and the RSS, the Rashtriya Swayamsewak Sangh, has grown especially, since the late eighties, and maybe fallen already.  This movement distinguishes itself from the others in that it has not had an outspoken claim for a separate piece of land, but increased (religious) independence for the group members. The other ethnic movements have been directed against the centre in general and its authority to keep the territory together in particular. The Hindu movement can be said to react against the secular role of the Indian state; possibly it is a follower-up of the middle and upper caste movement reacting against the government-imposed job Mandala- quotas for lower-caste members.  Other demands throughout the 1980s were that measures be taken against the equal status of local and regional languages and English with Hindi and the abolition of article 370 of the Indian constitution granting Kashmir a status of its own as semi-independent.
 Since this movement is not reacting against the whole centre - the supporters and financiers are too much involved in it themselves, being middle-class, partly state-class and partly NRE/middle class, and supported by a few wealthy families  - they have taken it out on the ethnic groups in the periphery. The destruction of a Muslim holy shrine the Babri Masjid Mosque in Ayodhya in December 1992, and the following riots between Hindus and Muslims in which 1700 people were killed were the main outbreaks of violence started by this movement. Following my argument that ethnicism is relative to surroundings, it seems clear that Hindus „took it out“ on the largest minority group, the Muslims, who also constitute the bottom layers of the caste system. One of the VHP’s calls in the early stages of mobilisation was a demand that the centre withdraw article 370 from the Indian constitution, an article granting Kashmir a certain degree of autonomy.  Both Sikhs and Muslims have been the victims of Hindu pogroms in the 1980s and 1990s.
 It seems as if the middle class is the driving force in ethnic mobilisation, and particularly sensitive to increased competition. Why? Prem Shankar Jha explains this with their vulnerability to interethnic competition. A small-scale manufacturer risks losing more after competition has been increased (or if they perceive it as such) than larger enterprises.
 The Hindus have mobilised in an urban area, but the causal connection cannot be verified. Prem Shankar Jha claims on the other hand, that where Hindu demonstrations were frequent and violent, Muslims also mobilised, even if this was on the obscure countryside. In India, at least, places where clashes between different ethnic groups have occurred before, seem to be those where ethnic animosities regularly get ignited. Therefore urbanisation should be complemented or replaced with a paragraph about increased inter-ethnic contact.
 As a difference from Kashmiri and Sikh militancy, can be mentioned, that the middle class Hindus involved in it, react against the secularism of the Indian state, and not the whole centre.
 It is could be doubted whether it can really count as an ethnic uprising, because it does not have a claim for land. They instead lodge claims for increased religious and therefore political freedom. Other factors influencing their mobilisation may be growing corruption, a fragile democracy etc but these are not group-specific.
 Competition has had a more evident role in this  movement than in the other cases studied, since it followed the reforms, the decision by VP Singh’s Janata Dal Government to implement the mandala quotas, according to which 27% of all jobs in the state sector were to go to members of the lower castes and the OBCs (the Other Backward Classes, the caste-less).  Not only the arguments for mobilisation and uprising may differ from reality, but both may also differ from the outlet of ethnic frustration and violence.
 Like in the Punjab (Akali Dal), this ethnic movement was taken up by one established political party (the BJP) meeting populist ethnic demands from the electorate and changing stances towards an increasingly nationalist (ethnocentric) discourse. They could be related with each other in that once the Punjabis (as well as the Kashmiris) had challenged the centre, the Hindu Right felt that they could challenge it too.
 We can therefore modify Olzak and Nagel’s proposition that political organisation as a part of modernisation increases ethnic mobilisation. A political institution will contrary to this claim in many cases use the ethnic group’s aspirations for independence and their mobilisation in order to get larger shares of the electorate. Like in Kashmir, the movements erupt in violence, when the political channels seem used up. Violent ethnicism is therefore, like war, politics with other means. If political freedom is granted, ethnic sentiment and ethnic politics will be expressed through the established channels.
 Hindu, Kashmiri, and Sikh ethnicism (if we can call them ethnic - all are in one way or another doubtful) share the difficulties in keeping uprisings united against the centre, especially so in the second armed step for independence. Co-optation may be easy in mobilisation, but not later. Therefore the competition model’s increased scales of organisation as ignitor of ethnicism rests upon a non-distinction between mobilisation and armed fight for independence.
 In the Punjab, the relative wealth and the establishment of the Sikhs in Indian society work stabilisingly. If this was not so, and interethnic competition was increased, more Sikhs would feel tempted to mobilise.

8. Conclusions.
8.1 A challenge to the system?
 The corruption, the informal market, the caste system, and the interdependence of all India cannot simply be abolished by decree, law, or credit liability conditions from international money-lenders. Through the release of market forces and by the opening up of trade and capital borders, the NRE and other challengers to the Centre have gained strength.  Subsequently Indian stability gets undermined as a result of the splitting-up of Congress and in the increased challenge to and the undermining of the secular Indian State.
 The conditions for the various ethnic uprisings mentioned differ enormously. One of the uprisings, the Hindu nationalist movement, is directed not against the centre in general because the nationalists themselves are tightly linked up with it, but against secularism in particular.  This is taken out on the periphery, and quite naturally on the Muslims who form the largest ethnic minority with 12% of the Indian population and who further deny the caste-system (and hence many of the structures mentioned) and distinguish themselves markedly from the Hindus  (80% of the Indian population of 929 million).
 The relativity clause of ethnicism means that, since the Hindus have mobilised on grounds of other, surrounding ethnic mobilisations, they have done so in order to both identify themselves with the group, and to shut out others, i.e. to discriminate against competing groups. Because these have mobilised on religious grounds, the Hindu self-proclaimed „defenders of the faith“ have done so likewise. Just as ethnic subjectivity refers to the divergence between fact and reasons for ethnic mobilisation, relativity accounts for the relationship between those two, but tries to explain ethnic movements as reactions against other groups. The societal structures soothe or ignite the eruption of ethnic violence.
 Instances of resurgent mobilisation based on tradition, history, and a long period of homogenous culture may mobilise easier than other, emergent or „new“ ones, especially if the former have a separate piece of land which they can lay claims to, but the success of their continued armed fight for independence isn’t granted. But the resurgent/emergent distinction isn’t that clear. Of course all ethnic movements mobilising, like in the above mentioned case of internal colonialism, claim themselves to draw on old sentiments, for instance the Sikh religion, a Hindu heartland in the north, the Tamil culture, or the Dravidian history of independence from the north. These belong to the rhetoric used in order to attract members.
 The Tamil absence of ethnic violence - as opposed to the other ethnic movements studied - may largely depend on the lack of a distinct religion which could serve as a strong unifyer but also on slow economic growth.
 All „second-steppers“, even if violent, have failed partly as a result of divided loyalties arising out of dependence on or links with other parts of society.
 The ethnic movements in Kashmir and in the Punjab have been able to mobilise because neither the Sikhs nor the Muslims perceive themselves in terms of caste and therefore belong to the bottom layers or below the caste-system. But their success has not been greater because of this. Unlike the Hindu movement they have failed in their separatist violence because of the Government’s hard way of handling the conflict, apart from the normal lack of popular support in mobilisation brought about by other sorts of dependence that exist in India.  The stagnation of the rightwing Hinduism is therefore the clearest indication of that my thesis about interdependence-imposing structures in society is right.

 If one group manages to break free from the nation-state’s hegemonic and violent control, other groups seem eager to try this too. Many outbreaks of ethnic violence occur as reactions to other groups. In India, where the main task of the centre has been to incorporate Hindus and non-Hindus, many ethnic groups mobilise on these grounds, i.e. pro or contra central secularism. The success in achieving independence may to some point (in the amount of support they can gather) depend on in what way the group mobilises. This, as seen, is largely determined by society and other groups.
 The structures of dependence, hierarchy, and control serve to stabilise society and maintain the social hierarchy in favour of non-lower caste, educated, male Hindus, preferably with connections to the state-class or the Congress party. The more one ethnie fits into this pattern, the more power is it likely to have. But as seen in the stagnation of the Hindu resurgence, the more tightly will its members be firstly dependent on other parts of society, and secondly linked to the state-class, therefore also on the centre’s role as a defender of secularism and stability.

8.2. The implications for the Competition Model
 According to the competition model, the ethnic competition for capital gains and political influence could provoke ethnic mobilisation.  Some of the Indian examples of ethnic uprisings may fit into this on a case-by-case basis. But in order to challenge the strong grip on Indian society that the centre still has and topple stability, would mean firstly to be able to co-optate peripheral groups (to overbridge all or many of the tugs) and secondly to erode the structural servant and corruption  networks making for dependence, hierarchy, and control in India, which thereby have a stabilising ot hegemonic control function.
The competition model is right in:
 most of its presuppositions. Increased competition for resources may have had a say in providing ethnicism in the Punjab , the Hindu heartland , Tamil Nadu, and in the Kashmir valley with subjective or rhetorical reasons for mobilising. They all lack, to some extent, unity and popular support, which is seen in their stagnation at various stages on the road to separatism.
 Other aspects of modernisation, like urbanisation and improved channels for communication may also make for increased ethnic awareness.  But all these things belong to the recruitment (identification) rhetoric of ethnic mobilisation. The second step is determined by the state of the nation-state. If it is falling apart, nearly any group will take to arms. Even if the groups mobilise on grounds of identification (religion as the Indian example), which are determined by society and other competing groups, their second step’s success is determined by both the State and how much popular support/unity they can gather.

It is not right in that:
 the increased opportunity to organise politically ignites. It may contribute to easify mobilisation just as any other form of social debate. But in the cases studied, it seems to be normal for the established political parties to take up ethnic sentiments on their policy agenda. If this continues, the ethnic movement will dissolve in the realm of politics, which is probably the case in Tamil Nadu, or break out in violence, like in the three other cases. This it does, when the political channels have been exhausted (or seem to be so to the ethnic freedom fighters).

 Supranational organisations may contribute at the State level. In the words of Kolodner:
    „The extraction of the state from the economic sector undermines the image of the government as the protector of citizens’ welfare, exacerbates the electorate’s dissatisfaction with the ruling Congress Party, and produces an authority vacuum.“
 Despice for politicians and accusations of corruption go hand in hand with another and create a general sense of distrust among the public and contribute to the centre’s dissolving.
 The expansion of the secondary and tertiary sectors, which is rapid in India, may also help in creating insecurity. And increased inter-ethnic contact may make for increased ethnic awareness.
 But these are only parts of a general sense of distrust and insecurity, which may increase or easify ethnic mobilisation. Even if the different ethnies will claim the opposite, these are devices of rhetoric, which have nothing to do with outbreaks of ethnic violence.
 
The competition model lacks:
 1) a clear distinction between mobilisation and the second-step, the outbreak of an armed separatist fight. Mobilisation for instance cannot fail. It goes on persistently and not all mobilising ethnic movements take to arms, for example the Tamils. Their mobilisation has not yet erupted, whereas the others have stagnated in their fight for separatism. Hindu, Kashmiri, and Sikh ethnicism share the difficulties in keeping uprisings united against the centre, especially so in the second armed step for independence. Co-optation may be easy in mobilisation, but not later. It is in the second step that movements fail, through interior splits and/or because society has grown able to handle uprising more indirectly by dependence structures in society. Mobilisation in India is directly counteracted by the centre by hegemonic (of which secularism can be said to be part) and violent control. Therefore the competition model’s increased scales of organisation as ignitor of ethnicism (see below) rests upon a non-distinction between mobilisation and armed fight for independence.

 2) clarification in the question of political organisation and increased scales of organisation. What is the ultimate size of the ethnie? Increased scales are good at one point. But these may disintegrate, particularly so if the ethnic identification is „weak“, i.e. if it rests on loose grounds like in pluralistic Kashmir, or hinder the second step, like in Tamil Nadu. In India, the least loose instances, which also seem to become the most violent, are those resting on anti - or pro-Hinduism, since Hinduism defends the very pillars of Indian society.

 3) a systemic framework for incorporating the role of the state, which in India has been both hegemonic and violent. According to Gurharpal Singh, Eric Kolodner, and Prem Shankar Jha, it has been increasingly directed at violence whereas before it used to be hegemonic. Singh claims that this has increased the Sikh ethnic nationalism. All „second-steppers“, even if violent, have failed to establish separatism partly as a result of divided loyalties arising out of dependence on or links with other parts of society.
 Discoursive mobilisation always goes on, in every society. The surroundings shape the form of ethnicism, and its success. The link between fact and rhetoric is sometimes perceived as subjective, but the second step, whether mobilisation leads to an outbreak of ethnic violence seems to depend on four factors: the role of the state, the role of integration with society, and the preceding outbreaks of violence. These factors clarify the link between increased interethnic competition and ethnic „mobilisation“.
 The causality between the competition model’s propositions (seen as conditions under which ethnicism is likely to mobilise, not erupt in violence) and the actual outbreak of ethnic violence could be explained by this. The structures in India and the centre’s strategy versus the periphery, have relied to a large extent on the mobilisative change in discourse, or in Singh’s words, on hegemonic control. Once violent control has been introduced, there will be no safety nets to fall back on for the centre. The outbreaks of violent ethnicism elsewhere in the region or country and in what state of disintegration the country is in. If one group starts the armed fight for independence, others may follow, either cheered by their neighbours, or (if they stand on different sides of the religious barrier) as a reaction against these.
 Central to this argument is however that mobilisation and outbreaks of ethnic violence are distinguished, and that the apparently arbitrary connection between the mobilisers’ arguments and the targets for violence get clarified. This I try to explain with what I have called „relative ethnicity“.

4) relativisation of the ethnic mobilisation to other, competing ethnic groups. It seems likely that the three outbreaks of ethnicism in the North, and the lack of one in the South, as well as the timeframe during which they have occurred as well as their succession are in some way temporally and geographically related.
 „Identities are always relational and what matters is not the representation of the Other as such, but the actual nature of the difference that is constructed. The issue then is one of diversity or division...solidarity or exclusion.“

 Most protruding is the fact that ethnic violence and the grounds of mobilisation seem separated. Here too a clearer distinction between mobilisation and the second-step is needed.

 Ethnicism is just one form of social mobilisation, fully comparable with other sorts of nationalism, racism, tribalism etc. It is partly the structure of society which decides which form the mobilisation is to take. In India the fundament for so much in society is ruled by Hindu prescription and the power of religion, that religious movements seem to inspire the largest amount of hatred and animosities. Those of other religions who challenge the Hindu pillars of India, are the main targets for the Hindu ethnic group.

 The distribution of resources as a consequence of reforms started too late to challenge the centre. The arisal of the NRE began long before the reforms. But the centre is dissolving, and ethnoregional claims for separatism seem to be increasing both in strength and in numbers. Increasingly these take, Hindu versus non-Hindu stances. But India hasn’t (yet) crumbled; the caste system, networks of corruption, servant structures, and parts of the state-class are still there as assistance to the centre and its secular unity.
 If new (mainly media-imposed) values in the wake of reforms and opened trade borders grow strong and common, they could subjugate the caste-dependency in the Indian mind and thereby threaten stability. It is however very much up to the centre and its strategies against the periphery, if ethnic mobilisations will take the second step and take to arms on their road to separatism.
 
Berlin, Germany, 29th Feb 1996

***

Literature:

Jörn Altmann: Wirtschaftspolitik, Gustav Fischer Verlag, Stuttgart und Jena, Germany, 1992
Gunilla Andrae and Björn Beckmann: The Wheat Trap. Bread and Underdevelopment in Nigeria, Zed Books, London, U.K. 1985
Pranab Bardhan, The Political Economy of Development in India, Basil Blackwell, Oxford, U.K., 1984
Frederick Barth (ed.), Ethnic Groups and Boundaries, Oslo, Norway, 1969
A.L. Basham: The Wonder That Was India, New Delhi, India, 1990
David Brown, The State and Ethnic Politics in Southeast Asia, Routledge, London and New York, 1994
Deutsche Bundesbank, Sonderdrucke, Nr. 3., Internationale Organisationen und Gremien im Bereich von Währung und Wirtschaft, Frankfurt am Main, Germany, 1992
R.S. Chaurasia, Indian Government and Politics, Forward Books, New Delhi, India, 1994
Robert Dahl, Modern Political Analysis, Prentice-Hall inc., Englewood Cliffs, N.J., U.S., 1984
Gerard Delanty, Inventing Europe. Idea, Identity, Reality. Macmillan Press, Ldn, 1995
Karl W. Deutsch, The Analysis of International Relations, Englewood Cliffs, N.J., U.S., 1991
Larry Diamond (ed.), Democracy in Developing Countries, Boulder Colorado, U.S., 1989
Michael Edwardes, Nehru. A Political Biography., Penguin Books Ltd., England, 1973
A.R. Gupta, Caste Hierarchy and Social Change, Sangeeta Printers, Maujpur, India, 1984
C. Harichandran, Panchayati Raj and Rural Development, a Study of Tamil Nadu, Naurung Rai Concept Publishing Co, India, 1983
Björn Hettne: Etniska Konflikter och Internationella Relationer, Studentlitteratur, Lund Sweden, 1992
Samuel Huntington, The Third Wave. Democratisation in the 20th Century, Norman, London U.K. 1991
ibid. The Clash of Civilizations,
Wolfgang S. Heinz, Menschenrechte in der Dritten Welt, C.H. Beck Verlagsges., Munich, Germany, 1986
Hague, Harrop, and Breslin, An Introduction to Comparative Government and Politics, London, UK, 1992
Instituto Tercer Mundo, Third World Guide, Montevideo, Uruguay 1993/94,
Eckart Koch, Internationale Wirtschaftsbeziehungen, Hoffmann und Campe Verlag, Bonn, Germany, 1992
Atul Kohli, Democracy and Discontent. India’s growing crises of governability, Cambridge University Press, England, 1990
Karl Marx, Friedrich Engels, V.I. Lenin, Über den revolutionären Weltprozeß, SED Parteipresse, Berlin, GDR 1971
G.R. Madan, India’s developing villages, Print House, India, 1983
Inder Malhoutra, India: Trapped in Uncertainty, Sangam Books, London, U.K., 1992
S.K. Misra and V.K. Puri, Structure and Problems of Indian Economy, Himalaya Publishing House, India, 1993
Jan Myrdal, Indien Väntar, Norstedts, Stockholm, Sweden, 1979
V.S. Naipaul: India. A Million Mutinies Now, Minerva Publishing Co, London, U.K., 1994
Dieter Nohlen and Franz Nuscheler, Handbuch der Dritten Welt, Band 7, Südasien und Südostasien, Hoffmann und Campe Verlag, Bonn, Germany, 1992
Omar Noman, Pakistan. A political and economic History since 1947, Kegan Paul, Ldn & N.Y., 1992
J.S. Railkar, Planning and Development Strategies, Sheth Publishers Pvt. Ltd, Bombay, India, 1990
Prem Shankar Jha, In the Eye of the Cyclone. The Crisis in Indian Democracy, VIKING/Penguin Books, New Delhi, India, 1993
Sung Moon Pae, Korea, Leading Developing Nations, Lanham, MD, US, 1992
I.A. Sondén-Haellquist, Indiens, Pakistans och Bangladesh’s Historia, Almqvist-Wicksell AB, Stockholm Sweden, 1971
Susan Strange: States and Markets. An Introduction to the International Political Economy, Pinter, London, U.K., 1986
Immanuel Wallenstein, Unthinking Social Science - the Limits of Nineteenth Century Paradigms, Basil Blackwell, Oxford, U.K., 1990
The World Bank, World Development Report, The World Bank, N.Y., USA, 1993

Scholarly essays:
 Hoshiar Singh, Constitutional Base for Panchayat Raj in India. The 73rd Amendment Act, Asian Survey, Vol. xxiv, no. 9, Sept. 1994.
 L.K. Jha: The Role of Foreign Collaboration and Trade in India’s Recent Economic Policies in Politische Vierteljahresberichte Nr. 110, Dec. 1987, p.365-367
 Abid Hussain: Reform and Liberalization ibid. p.369-371
Jürgen Wiemann: India’s Strategy of Self-reliance - Achievements, Shortcomings, and Perspectives, ibid. p.373-377
Arvind Panagariya, India: A New Tiger On the Block?, Journal of International Affairs, 48.1. Summer 1994
 Hartmut Elsenhans: Dependencia, Unterentwicklung und der Staat in der Dritten Welt, Politische Vierteljahresschrift, Heft 2., Juni 1986, p. 133-158
 Erich Weede, Warum bleiben arme Leute arm?, in PVS, H. 3, Sep. 1985, p. 270-286
Georg Simonis, Rent-seeking - eine neue Theorie der Unterentwicklung?, PVS, H. 1, Mar 1986, p. 100-108
Shankar Bhaduri Paramilitary has become a generalist force in The Asian Age, 27 Oct. 1994
Gurharpal Singh, The Punjab Crisis since 1984, in Ethnic and Racial Studies, Routledge, London, U.K., July 1995
Ethnic mobilisation:
S. Olzak, Ethnicity and theories of ethnic collective behaviour in Research on social movements, conflicts, and change, vol. 8, 1985
J. Nagel and S. Olzak, Ethnic mobilisation in new and old states:an extension of the competition model, in Social Problems, No. 30, 1982
Peter Waldmann, Ethnoregionalismus und Nationalstaat, Leviathan, Berlin, Germany, 3(21) 1993
Sarah Bèlanger and Maurice Pinard, Ethnic Movements and the Competition Model: Some missing Links, in American Sociological Review, Vol. 56, Aug. (?), pp. 446-457
Friedrich Heckmann, Ethnische Minderheiten, Volk und Nation:Soziologie interethnischer Beziehungen, Stuttgart, Germany, Henke Verlag
Marc Alan Howard, Die Ostdeutschen als ethnische Gruppe?, Berliner Debatte/Initial, 4/5 1995
 

Newspaper Articles:
Das Parlament, Themenausgabe Indien, Nr. 8-9, 19/26 Feb. 1993
Cover story, India Today, May 31, 1995
Sunil Jain: On the Edge Again, India Today, 30 Apr. 1995,
Changing Phase of Reforms, 31 Jan 1995,
Behind the Silver Lining, 31 Mar 1995
Torbjörn Petersson, Sjudande ekonomi ger indier framtidstro, Dagens Nyheter, 21 okt. 1995
ibid., Indisk bostadsbrist drabbar alla,DN, 22 okt 1995
Duvvudi Subbarao: Reforms with a human face. The Economic Time, 16 Feb. 1995,
Alok Muherjee, The Two-track Strategy, The Hindu, 31 March 1995,
T.K. Arun, Reforming the Reforms. The Economic Time, 17 Feb. 1995
Prabul Bichlai, Wages of Neglect- Economic of Congress Defeat, Times of India, 24 March 1995
C.H. Manumantha Rao, Structural Adjustment. Lessons from East Asian Experience, Times of India, 10 Feb 1995.
Gordon Crovitz and Hamish McDonald, Stability for sure, Far Eastern Economic Review, 2 Feb. 1995,
The Hindu „Our correspondent“, India Warned of Mexican-type Crisis, 26 March 1995
Hamish McDonald, Don’t stop now The reform agenda and Reality Check. Opposition parties gradually embrace change, FEER 2 Feb. 1995,Limited Express, 27 Apr 1995
Shefali Rekhi, Foreign Investors: Catching Their Eye, IT 15 Mar 1995
Narendar Pani, Diminishing returns from reforms, ECT 23 Mar 1995,
Sanjaya Baru, The lesson India can learn from Mexico: Gradualism better than speed, Times of India 13 Jan 1995
Gabriele Venzky, Ein Gigant, der zur Reform nicht fähig ist, Der Tagesspiegel, 23 May 1995
Vermeintliche „Wunderwaffen“ gegen Hochmut und Armut, Der Tagesspiegel, May or June 1995
Bernard Imhasly Narasimha Raos Ochsentour, die tageszeitung, 9 Feb. 1995
Zafar Agha, Congress(I). The Face Lift, India Today 28 Feb. 1995,
Frankfurter Rundschau, Kongreßpartei schließt zahlreiche Abtrünnige aus, 22 May 1995,
Rahman and Zafar Agha, Congress(I) Ifs and Buts all the Way, ibid.

Yuburaj Ghimire, The Saffron Resurgence, India Today, 31 March 1995
BJP: Brimming with Hope, IT 15 Mar 1995
India Today, November 15, 1995:
Ramesh Vinayak, Striking Terror, (Punjab),
Inderjit Badhwar, Why Rao’s Package is a Sham, (Kashmir)
Harinder Baweja and Nirupama Subramanian, Sri Lanka. The Danger at the Doorstep.

Vasant Sathe, India should be governed by a directly elected President, Times of India 15 Feb 1995
Hannan Ezekiel, Reinventing Government. Accent Should Be On Efficiency, T.O.I., 25 Feb. 1995
Bernard Imhasly, Der hohle Klang der Muschel. Indiens Wahlkommissar versetzt die Politiker im Angst und Schrecken..., die tageszeitung, 4/5 February 1995
Inderjit Badhwar and Charu Lata Joshi, T.N. Seshan: „Narasimha Rao is hostile to me“, India Today, May 31, 1995

Thomas Avenarius, Kaschmirs langer kampf: Der Haß auf Indien wird immer größer, (caption very misleading from text contents), Süddeutsche Zeitung, Nr 119, May 1995

Unpublished material/own experience:
Hansi Elsbacher, Doing good things for the people. A report about Panchayat Raj and political power in a village in India, available in Swedish only at the Department of Political Science, Stockholm University, Sweden, or from the author. The fieldwork was carried out in Bommanampalayam, Coimbatore district, Tamil Nadu, September 1993. Other observations have been made during three other journeys mainly in the south of India in 1987/88, 1989/90, and 1993.
Hansi Elsbacher, Kastsystemet stabiliserar Indien, in Sydasien 1/96, Lund, Sweden 1996
 
 



 
 
  Back to Sight of India

 

If you have comments or suggestions, email me at hansi.elsbacher@sifo.se
This page created with Netscape Navigator Gold
1